2008
DOI: 10.2202/1935-1690.1540
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The Dynamics of European Inflation Expectations

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1

Citation Types

10
51
2

Year Published

2008
2008
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
8
1

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 63 publications
(65 citation statements)
references
References 10 publications
(17 reference statements)
10
51
2
Order By: Relevance
“…Subsequently, a number of contributions have studied the expectations-formation process in more detail. With regard to the updating frequency, Doepke, Dovern, Fritsche, and Slacalek (2008) apply Carroll's framework to European data, and report a somewhat lower updating frequency of around 18 months. Using the Michigan Consumer Survey microdata, Dräger and Lamla (2012) provide evidence that quantitative in ‡ation expectations are adjusted rel-atively frequently, whereas the qualitative assessment (whether prices in general will go up, down or stay where they are now) changes less often.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Subsequently, a number of contributions have studied the expectations-formation process in more detail. With regard to the updating frequency, Doepke, Dovern, Fritsche, and Slacalek (2008) apply Carroll's framework to European data, and report a somewhat lower updating frequency of around 18 months. Using the Michigan Consumer Survey microdata, Dräger and Lamla (2012) provide evidence that quantitative in ‡ation expectations are adjusted rel-atively frequently, whereas the qualitative assessment (whether prices in general will go up, down or stay where they are now) changes less often.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Specifically, our study provides evidence of staggered updating of inflation expectations of households for Europe. In contrast to Döpke et al (2008), however, our econometric framework allows us to trace the stickiness of expectations at every moment in time. This is realized via a Bayesian state-space model featuring time-varying parameters and variances.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Looking at the movements of forecast errors in relation to the variable being forecasted Coibion and Gorodnichenko (2008) and Coibion (2010) document pervasive and robust evidence consistent with information rigidities. For Europe Döpke et al (2008) show that consumers update their inflation expectations once every 18 months. In sum these studies provide evidence for staggered updating and for information frictions.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The theoretical model states that the difference between inflation expectations and realised inflation is determined by an autoregressive part and a part that can be described as For the autoregressive part, we assume that we can approximate expectations for inflation five months ahead by using inflation expectations formed one period before, π t+5|t ≈ π t+5|t−1 (see Döpke et al 2005). In addition to this, we estimate the unrestricted model where the coefficient of the lagged endogenous variable is not bound to be one.…”
Section: The Relation Between the Inflation Rate And Inflation Expectmentioning
confidence: 99%