2015
DOI: 10.1016/j.jinteco.2015.05.004
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Structural gravity with dummies only: Constrained ANOVA-type estimation of gravity models

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

3
124
0
1

Year Published

2015
2015
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

2
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 143 publications
(145 citation statements)
references
References 43 publications
3
124
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…It is well documented in the literature that trade grew substantially in all major regions of the world over the last decades; furthermore, the liberalization of discriminatory and nondiscriminatory trade policy measures is partly responsible for this development (see Baier andBergstrand 2001, Egger andNigai 2015). Important policy changes in that vein were the conclusion of the GATT (General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade) and WTO (World Trade Organization) rounds, as well as the formation of what Baldwin (2006) called the "spaghetti bowl" of preferential trade agreements.…”
Section: Globalization and Relative Labor Income Tax Burdens Acrosmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…It is well documented in the literature that trade grew substantially in all major regions of the world over the last decades; furthermore, the liberalization of discriminatory and nondiscriminatory trade policy measures is partly responsible for this development (see Baier andBergstrand 2001, Egger andNigai 2015). Important policy changes in that vein were the conclusion of the GATT (General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade) and WTO (World Trade Organization) rounds, as well as the formation of what Baldwin (2006) called the "spaghetti bowl" of preferential trade agreements.…”
Section: Globalization and Relative Labor Income Tax Burdens Acrosmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Because proxy variables provide only approximate information on the economic process in the background, they are likely to contain noise (measurement error) which can be separated from the systematic variation when imposing a set of suitable assumptions. In general, Egger and Nigai (2014) provide evidence that parameterized trade cost functions appear to generally lead to sizable measurement errors with aggregate gravity models of bilateral international trade. In the introduction, we gave examples of earlier work that pointed to measurement problems with specific observable trade cost variables.…”
Section: A Random Coefficients Gravity Modelmentioning
confidence: 97%
“…This paper proposes an alternative approach, where at least observable (and, eventually, even unobservable) measures of trade costs may exert a direct effect on bilateral trade that is variable. It is well known that the measurement of many variables entering gravity-model specifications is imprecise (see Egger and Nigai 2014): Tariff rates may be improperly applied to the wrong product lines due to fraud (Fisman and Wei 2004) or may be badly recorded; distances between countries pertain to some arbitrary points in space (capital cities or economic centers) which may coincide with origins and destinations of exports and imports or not (see Hillberry and Hummels 2008); adjacency might matter differently for country pairs with longer or shorter borders (see Engel and Rogers 1996); common official language may mis-represent the importance of the actual overlap of (native or non-native) speakers between two countries (see Melitz and Toubal 2014); and domestic as opposed to foreign trade costs might be mis-measured (see Rousslang and To 1993). These issues of measurement error as well as specific responses per se might lead to heterogeneous direct effects of trade impediments on trade flows, which are typically assumed to be the same.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Hence, we can use the relationshiplnλni,tjλii,tj=ei,tj+din,tjen,tj,where ej,ts and en,tj are data on (log) unit‐cost measures. Hence, we can calculate trade costs in year t as:τin,tj=exp1θj1emdin,tjThen we can trace how trade costs changed across time and, using hat algebra for changes, definetrueτ^in,tj=τin,tj/τin,1995j.This approach is related to Egger and Nigai (). We plot the change in trade costs for agricultural goods, manufactures, and services across different percentiles of the data in Figure .…”
Section: Calibrationmentioning
confidence: 99%