2008
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1266219
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Learning and Heterogeneity in GDP and Inflation Forecasts

Abstract: We estimate a Bayesian learning model with heterogeneity aimed at explaining the evolution of expert disagreement in forecasting real GDP growth and inflation over 24 monthly horizons for G7 countries during 1990-2007. Professional forecasters are found to begin and have relatively more success in predicting inflation than real GDP at significantly longer horizons; forecasts for real GDP contain little information beyond 6 quarters, but forecasts for inflation have predictive value beyond 24 months and even 36… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
3
0

Year Published

2009
2009
2016
2016

Publication Types

Select...
5

Relationship

0
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 6 publications
(3 citation statements)
references
References 68 publications
0
3
0
Order By: Relevance
“…The time span we consider goes from the second quarter of 1999 (1999Q2) to the second quarter of 2015 (2015Q2) for GDP growth and from September 1999 (1999Q3) to September 2015 (2015Q3) for inflation, as that is the period that we can compare with the forecasts given by the ECB-SPF. There are two additional issues regarding the data: (1) The euro area for the time period analyzed has expanded; while in the year 2000 it was formed by 11 countries, in 2015 it includes 19 countries, and (2) GDP growth data are subject to important revisions and final data may not correspond with the figures that forecasters first observed in real time (see, for instance, Lahiri and Sheng (2010a)). The problem of revisions is smaller when looking at inflation.…”
Section: Consensus Forecast Behavior and Alternative Dimension Reductmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The time span we consider goes from the second quarter of 1999 (1999Q2) to the second quarter of 2015 (2015Q2) for GDP growth and from September 1999 (1999Q3) to September 2015 (2015Q3) for inflation, as that is the period that we can compare with the forecasts given by the ECB-SPF. There are two additional issues regarding the data: (1) The euro area for the time period analyzed has expanded; while in the year 2000 it was formed by 11 countries, in 2015 it includes 19 countries, and (2) GDP growth data are subject to important revisions and final data may not correspond with the figures that forecasters first observed in real time (see, for instance, Lahiri and Sheng (2010a)). The problem of revisions is smaller when looking at inflation.…”
Section: Consensus Forecast Behavior and Alternative Dimension Reductmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…CE reports average annual growth rates of expected inflation for the current and the next calendar year. However, since the forecast horizon varies for each month, the cross-sectional dispersion of forecasts is strongly seasonal and converges towards zero at the end of each year (Lahiri and Sheng, 2010a). To obtain twelve-month-ahead inflation forecasts, we follow Dovern et al (2009) and calculate a weighted moving average of the annual forecasts.…”
Section: Survey-based Measuresmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…1 In Lahiri and Sheng (2008) and Lahiri and Sheng (2010a), disagreement across forecasters arises due to differences in individual forecasters' prior beliefs, differences in processing new information, and differences in the relative importance that forecasters attach to their priors and the new information. This framework is especially useful to describe situations in which a sequence of forecasts (with shrinking forecast horizon) is made for one particular random variable, such as an annual growth rate.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%