2006
DOI: 10.1016/s1574-0676(06)01007-6
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Chapter 7 The Economic Analysis of Art Law

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1

Citation Types

0
6
0

Year Published

2009
2009
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
5

Relationship

0
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 6 publications
(11 citation statements)
references
References 8 publications
0
6
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Second, there is a high premium value attached to the original artwork and 'authenticity' in general (Watt et al, 2014). In a similar vein, Landes and Levine (2006) argue that the general economic case for copyright protection is weakened for unique works such as paintings since the artist's main income source is the first sale of the original work (in the absence of resale rights). Overall, for several reasons being copied seems less of a threat to visual artist's work and the appropriation of value than it is for writers, composers, or performers in other sectors (Landes & Levine, 2006).…”
Section: Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Second, there is a high premium value attached to the original artwork and 'authenticity' in general (Watt et al, 2014). In a similar vein, Landes and Levine (2006) argue that the general economic case for copyright protection is weakened for unique works such as paintings since the artist's main income source is the first sale of the original work (in the absence of resale rights). Overall, for several reasons being copied seems less of a threat to visual artist's work and the appropriation of value than it is for writers, composers, or performers in other sectors (Landes & Levine, 2006).…”
Section: Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Second, it may take the establishment of fair use rules or pre-set compensation schemes to overcome strategic hold-up and transaction costs problems around the efficient licensing of such reuses, in particular for productive rather than reproductive ones (Landes & Posner, 2003Posner, 2004). 4 Put differently, the economic efficiency around fair use can include circumstances with high transaction costs in which the benefits to the copier are higher than the costs of negotiation with the upstream right holder (Landes & Levine, 2006). For example, Watson (2017b) argues that hip-hop artists reusing pre-existing recordings (i.e., digital sampling in music) spend excess information and search costs before they can enter negotiations over licenses with the relevant right holders.…”
Section: Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Thus, proponents of moral rights laws argue that they increase the incentive for artists to produce, leading to a greater stock of innovative art. On the other hand, some economists (e.g., Landes 2001;Landes and Levine 2006) have argued that moral rights legislation most likely does not enhance social welfare and may even lead to net welfare decreases. They point out that the costs of these laws may be higher than the benefits, particularly because the limitations imposed by the laws may deter buyers.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Landes (2001) andLandes and Levine (2006) present a thorough discussion of the various cases tried in court under this legislation. Additional cases have been settled out of court.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…goods (see Landes & Levine, 2006;Townley & Gulledge, 2015) in that it can be considered both an economic asset and as embodied cultural capital (Hanquinet, Roose, & Savage, 2014). Large amounts of money invested in the art market circulate throughout the world (Goetzmann, Renneboog, & Spaenjers, 2011).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%