2006
DOI: 10.1007/s00182-006-0056-z
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

A spatial voting model where proportional rule leads to two-party equilibria

Abstract: Voting, Proportional rule, Nash equilibria, C72, D72,

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1

Citation Types

1
48
0

Year Published

2009
2009
2016
2016

Publication Types

Select...
5
3

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 46 publications
(49 citation statements)
references
References 22 publications
1
48
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Additionally, polarization may have a strong negative effect on economic performance and growth (Frye ) and increase the risk of social tension and violent conflict within and between nation‐states (Esteban and Schneider ). Among several alternative theories proposed, one can attribute polarization to a wide range of forces spanning from informational or media‐related factors (e.g., DellaVigna and Kaplan ; Grosser and Palfrey ) to candidates' differing policy preferences (e.g., Calvert ; Roemer ).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Additionally, polarization may have a strong negative effect on economic performance and growth (Frye ) and increase the risk of social tension and violent conflict within and between nation‐states (Esteban and Schneider ). Among several alternative theories proposed, one can attribute polarization to a wide range of forces spanning from informational or media‐related factors (e.g., DellaVigna and Kaplan ; Grosser and Palfrey ) to candidates' differing policy preferences (e.g., Calvert ; Roemer ).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“… The mean decision rule is also analyzed in other contexts, such as, Gibbons (1988) and De Sinopoli and Iannantuoni (2000). …”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…h(t) = (E X j [X j ] + t)/2) and the normalization of the distribution. To obtain the second property, preferences is normally the median voter's preferred decision (see the literature following Black, 1948), whereas the average aggregation rule resembles proportional representation (Ortuño-Ortín, 1997;De Sinopoli and Iannantuoni, 2007). Example 2: joint responsibility versus individual responsibility.…”
Section: Appendix a Auxiliary Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The average aggregation rule with the optimal report space in my setting can be interpreted as optimal delegation in the sense of Holmström (1984). The average aggregation rule in combination with a given non-optimal report space is studied in a number of articles (e.g., Rausser et al, 2015;De Sinopoli and Iannantuoni, 2007;Renault andTrannoy, 2005 andCai, 2009). 10 Holmström (1984) poses the delegation problem and discusses optimal interval delegation in some examples.…”
Section: The Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%