2010
DOI: 10.1787/eco_studies-2010-5kmh5x51fv5f
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

What is the private return to tertiary education?

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1

Citation Types

0
22
0

Year Published

2014
2014
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 26 publications
(22 citation statements)
references
References 10 publications
0
22
0
Order By: Relevance
“…3 For comparisons of gross wage premia from tertiary education across countries, see Boarini and Strauss (2010). A recent paper studying returns to cognitive skills is Hanushek et al (2015).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…3 For comparisons of gross wage premia from tertiary education across countries, see Boarini and Strauss (2010). A recent paper studying returns to cognitive skills is Hanushek et al (2015).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…and the opportunity costs, in terms of foregone labour market earnings, associated with participation in tertiary education. Oliveira Martins et al (2009) show that higher internal rates of return -as estimated by Boarini and Strauss (2010) -lead to higher graduation rates in a panel of 20 OECD countries.…”
Section: Demand For Tertiary Educationmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Second, the computation of an internal rate of return is very data intensive, which would limit the sample size. While Boarini and Strauss (2010) construct all-encompassing internal rates of return for 21 OECD countries, the data requirements and the complexity of the computations implied that estimates were only produced for a fairly limited sample of country-years, with the latest year for most countries being 2001. Thirdly, the simplified approach is more flexible in that it allows the impact of different demand components to deviate from the restrictions that an all-encompassing internal rate of return equation would impose.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For instance, the wage profiles of men and women are different; the genderspecific rates of unemployment are different; the length of their active lives are different; unemployment benefits are (or may be) different, due (mostly) to wage differences; public policies affect men and women in different ways. Gender-specific returns on education have been computed, using de la Fuente's model, for 21 OECD countries by Boarini and Strauss (2010). We also adopt his 2003 model to estimate the returns on education for men.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…However, to study all the possible factors driving the gender gap in the rates of return, we take the de la Fuente model one step further by also considering some parameters related to maternity issues that can affect the incentive to invest in education and to participate to the labour market for women (see Del Boca, Locatelli, Pasqua and Pronzato (2003)). Hence, our model differs from that of Boarini and Strauss (2010) mainly in how it deals with women (and for the econometric procedure adopted in the estimate of the Mincerian coefficients that they use). The actual female work experience may be affected by maternity episodes and, consequently, by maternity leave and maternity-related monetary benefits (Mac (2003), Mahon (2002), Brewster and Rindfuss (2000), Blackburn, Bloom and Neumark (1993)).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%