1989
DOI: 10.2307/3324934
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Water Transfers, Irrigation Districts, and the Compensation Problem

Abstract: Despite statutory reforms and potentially large economic gains from water trades, water markets have been slow to develop throughout the West. This article examines an institutional impediment that has not received adequate attention: How can irrigation districts structure water trades to benefit their customers? I t shows how this question can be satisfactorily answered by organizing a proposed water trade like a friendly corporate tender offer. While seemingly a radical procedure, the method conforms with a … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

1
8
0

Year Published

1991
1991
2014
2014

Publication Types

Select...
8

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 12 publications
(9 citation statements)
references
References 0 publications
1
8
0
Order By: Relevance
“…About 70% of IDs in the Valley have initial agricultural water right holdings equal or greater than 6,000 AF (municipal equivalent). The findings reinforce the literature in water economics where population growth has been described as one of the influential factors in agriculture to municipal water transfers in the American west (Smith, ; Watson and Davies, ; Libecap, ). Higher population and consequent industrialization and urbanization create pressure for water demand and opportunities for win‐win water transfers.…”
Section: Resultssupporting
confidence: 88%
“…About 70% of IDs in the Valley have initial agricultural water right holdings equal or greater than 6,000 AF (municipal equivalent). The findings reinforce the literature in water economics where population growth has been described as one of the influential factors in agriculture to municipal water transfers in the American west (Smith, ; Watson and Davies, ; Libecap, ). Higher population and consequent industrialization and urbanization create pressure for water demand and opportunities for win‐win water transfers.…”
Section: Resultssupporting
confidence: 88%
“…Typically, the districts are nonprofit organizations with limited governmental powers, including limited taxation powers [Leshy, 1982]. Because irrigation districts have no profit motive and, further, are generally unregulated, they have little incentive to improve the technical and allocative efficiency of water consumption [Smith, 1989]. In particular, their rate structures commonly price water at average cost, and they rarely make even temporary water transfers outside their geographic service areas.…”
Section: The Individual Water User Typically Does Not Own the Reclamamentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The irrigation district could serve as the facilitator of water conservation and transfer activities. Smith [1989], however, has written on the inherent problems of distributing the benefits of districtqevel water marketing activity among the final water users. He finds that coordination problems within irrigation districts explain to some degree the relatively small number of transfers negotiated at the irrigation district level.…”
Section: Water Conservation Subsidies a Program Subsidizingmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…1989: 509, italics in original).& A point of clarification is in order about farmers selling their "rights." California irrigation district enabling law bestows on farmers "implicit rights in the district's water supply" (Smith 1989). These are rights to equitable and beneficial use of the district's water.…”
Section: Water Transfers and Economic Theorymentioning
confidence: 99%