2004
DOI: 10.1016/j.jebo.2003.11.004
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Trust, risk and betrayal

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

24
400
5
5

Year Published

2011
2011
2020
2020

Publication Types

Select...
3
3
2

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 640 publications
(472 citation statements)
references
References 29 publications
24
400
5
5
Order By: Relevance
“…However, people were quite averse to giving the $5 to Person B when that person would flip a coin to determine the fate of the $20, despite such behavior being just as altruistic and efficient. Data from other studies shows this same pattern: Adding payoffs to other people beyond the self in a coin flip fails to inspire more gambling among participants (Bohnet & Zeckhauser, 2004;Schlösser, Fetchenhauer, & Dunning, 2013;Schlösser, Mensching, Dunning, & Fetchenhauer, 2014). Further, people are not influenced in the trust game by whether their interaction partner is poor, and thus needs the money, or is rich (Brülhart & Usunier, 2012).…”
Section: On Alternative Accountsmentioning
confidence: 83%
“…However, people were quite averse to giving the $5 to Person B when that person would flip a coin to determine the fate of the $20, despite such behavior being just as altruistic and efficient. Data from other studies shows this same pattern: Adding payoffs to other people beyond the self in a coin flip fails to inspire more gambling among participants (Bohnet & Zeckhauser, 2004;Schlösser, Fetchenhauer, & Dunning, 2013;Schlösser, Mensching, Dunning, & Fetchenhauer, 2014). Further, people are not influenced in the trust game by whether their interaction partner is poor, and thus needs the money, or is rich (Brülhart & Usunier, 2012).…”
Section: On Alternative Accountsmentioning
confidence: 83%
“…Actual trust behavior, as measured for instance by the amount of money that a person would be willing to lend to an unknown individual, obviously depends both on the belief the lender has about the borrower's trustworthiness as well as on the lender's willingness to bear the risk that the borrower does not repay. When faced with -social risk‖ -that is the risk that a loss is caused by another person rather than nature -what matters is betrayal aversion (Bohnet and Zeckhauser, 2004) -that is the dislike for the risk of being cheated, not risk aversion. By using the German Socio-Economic Panel (which collects measures of trust, risk preferences and betrayal aversion), Fehr (2009) collected by Bohnet et al (2008) seems to suggest that risk and betrayal preferences do differ, though sample sizes are not large enough to draw strong conclusions (see also Naef et al 2008).…”
Section: Measuring Trust In Surveysmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Our starting point, when thinking about how to achieve this was Bohnet and Zeckhauser's (2004) experiment designed to isolate and measure betrayal (of trust) aversion. In their experiment the trusters and trustees in one treatment and the gamble choosers in the other, made eitheror decisions.…”
Section: The No Accomplice (Nac) Variantmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In their experiment the trusters and trustees in one treatment and the gamble choosers in the other, made eitheror decisions. This being the case, Bohnet and Zeckhauser (2004) could effectively hold all other things, except the existence of the trustees but including the trusters' ex ante subjective distributions of monetary payoffs conditional on their own decisions, constant by asking the trusters and gamble choosers for their "minimum acceptable probabilities (MAPs) of getting the good outcome such that they would prefer the chance to the sure payoff" (p.467). In this context, betrayal aversion manifests as trusters reporting higher MAPs relative to gamble choosers.…”
Section: The No Accomplice (Nac) Variantmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation