2015
DOI: 10.1016/j.enpol.2015.05.020
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The simple economics of motor vehicle pollution: A case for fuel tax

Abstract: The volume of pollution produced by an automobile is determined by driver's behavior along three margins: (i) vehicle selection, (ii) kilometers driven, and (iii) on-road fuel economy. The first two margins have been studied extensively, however the third has received scant attention. How significant is this 'intensive margin'? What would be the optimal policies when it is taken into account? The paper develops and analyzes a simple model of the technical and behavioral mechanisms that determine the volume emi… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

0
13
0

Year Published

2016
2016
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

1
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 32 publications
(13 citation statements)
references
References 59 publications
0
13
0
Order By: Relevance
“…A tax on fuel which equals the marginal damage of CO2 emissions, a tax on driving distance which equals the marginal damage of mileage-related externalities, and a zero tax on fuel-intensive vehicles, also implements the social planner solution. 2 Both these solutions lead to a more efficient allocation of vehicles and driving distance than the solution with a uniform tax on fuel combined with taxation of fuel-intensive vehicles; see also Ashley et al (2017) and Montag (2015). However, a GPS-based system is more costly to administer and is likely to impose information-processing costs and undesirable surveillance; see Parry et al (2007).…”
Section: Other Tax Instrumentsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…A tax on fuel which equals the marginal damage of CO2 emissions, a tax on driving distance which equals the marginal damage of mileage-related externalities, and a zero tax on fuel-intensive vehicles, also implements the social planner solution. 2 Both these solutions lead to a more efficient allocation of vehicles and driving distance than the solution with a uniform tax on fuel combined with taxation of fuel-intensive vehicles; see also Ashley et al (2017) and Montag (2015). However, a GPS-based system is more costly to administer and is likely to impose information-processing costs and undesirable surveillance; see Parry et al (2007).…”
Section: Other Tax Instrumentsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Some works have analysed the impact of air pollution policies on the structural changes at sectorial level and on energy use (Bollena and Brink, 2014;Naqvi and Zwickl, 2017). Others consider that the volume of pollution produced by an automobile is determined by drivers' behaviour vis--vis three criteria (vehicle selection, kilometres driven, and on-road fuel economy) and they study the optimal policies which could change the driver's behaviour (Montag, 2015). Agostinia and Jimnez (2015) have focused on the gasoline tax as the best instrument of climate policy.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…driven (Fischer, Harrington, and Parry, 2007;Parry and Small, 2005;Parry, Walls, and Harrington, 2007; see also Montag, 2015). This assumption implies bunching of measured emissions below the thresholds shown in Tab.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 93%
“…This means that producer has to compare costs on lowering the emissions with non-signifi cant gains. As a result, all new cars should produce a similar amount of air pollutants per kilometer 1 For recent medical literature see references in Montag (2015). Schwartz (2004) provides an excellent review of the literature on child-specifi c eff ects of air pollution.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%