2016
DOI: 10.1017/s0003055416000241
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The Primary Effect: Preference Votes and Political Promotions

Abstract: In this analysis of how electoral rules and outcomes shape the internal organization of political parties, we make an analogy to primary elections to argue that parties use preference-vote tallies to identify popular politicians and promote them to positions of power. We document this behavior among parties in Sweden's semi-open-list system and in Brazil's open-list system. To identify a causal impact of preference votes, we exploit a regression discontinuity design around the threshold of winning the most pre… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1

Citation Types

5
73
0
1

Year Published

2017
2017
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
7

Relationship

1
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 93 publications
(79 citation statements)
references
References 57 publications
(70 reference statements)
5
73
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…With pure rank-taking, parties' and voters' preferences regarding candidates would have to be alike for cue-taking to result in acceptable choices. There is some empirical evidence that this is the case, since parties in flexible list systems promote candidates who proved popular with voters in the past (more so than expected on the basis of list position) to more promising list ranks in subsequent elections (André et al 2015;Crisp et al 2013;Folke et al 2015). 36 Preferences of voters and parties need not coincide in all contexts, though.…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…With pure rank-taking, parties' and voters' preferences regarding candidates would have to be alike for cue-taking to result in acceptable choices. There is some empirical evidence that this is the case, since parties in flexible list systems promote candidates who proved popular with voters in the past (more so than expected on the basis of list position) to more promising list ranks in subsequent elections (André et al 2015;Crisp et al 2013;Folke et al 2015). 36 Preferences of voters and parties need not coincide in all contexts, though.…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…However, we do not believe that this is the case given the strong norm in Swedish national parties to honor the autonomy of their local parties. Recent work by Folke, Persson, and Rickne (2016) reinforces that view by citing documents from national party congress meetings.…”
mentioning
confidence: 82%
“…These estimates strongly indicate 18 As shown in online Appendix Table W1, when we use a continuous measure of competence, the baseline estimates in Table 4 and Figure 4 have the same signs as with the binary measure, although they are noisier and somewhat smaller in absolute value. 19 As further discussed in Folke, Persson, and Rickne (2016), data from a large mandatory survey of all post-election appointments made by local parties in the 2006 and 2010 elections show that the top-ranked politician on the largest majority party's ballot was appointed to the position of chairperson of the municipal council board (the equivalent of mayor) in nine out of ten cases. that our competence measure predicts direct voter support, in line with our model's core assumption.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…In open lists, not only nomination and election but also promotions to executive appointments depend on voter choice. Specifically, recent research finds that in open list systems, preference votes provide information on the popularity of party candidates and this doubles the probability of political appointments (Folke et al 2016). This direct relationship between preference votes and political appointments in open list systems provides strong incentives to politicians to be at least as concerned about serving their voters as the party leadership.…”
Section: Personal Vote and Ministerial Appointments In Parliamentary mentioning
confidence: 99%