1983
DOI: 10.4159/harvard.9780674497627
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The Future of Industrial Societies

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
28
0

Year Published

1991
1991
2020
2020

Publication Types

Select...
9

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 230 publications
(31 citation statements)
references
References 0 publications
0
28
0
Order By: Relevance
“…"In a more highly competitive industrial world where the technology is potentially nearly identical, where physical resources are distributed in world-wide markets, and where industrialism has left much the same imprint on many societies, what once may have seemed like small differences may have big results" (Kerr, 1983). For the doyen of American modernization theory, industrial relations are one of these small differences that bear large consequences.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…"In a more highly competitive industrial world where the technology is potentially nearly identical, where physical resources are distributed in world-wide markets, and where industrialism has left much the same imprint on many societies, what once may have seemed like small differences may have big results" (Kerr, 1983). For the doyen of American modernization theory, industrial relations are one of these small differences that bear large consequences.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Structural explanations hold that national differences become less pronounced with "modernization", though the path and speed of convergence may vary across countries (Kerr et al, 1960). The observed divergence in patterns of industrial relations, union organization and industrial conflict is interpreted as an exception to convergence rather than as a challenge to the assumption of a universalistic logic (Kaelble, 1987;Kerr, 1983).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…There have inevitably been debates about the applicability of standard social class measures in central and eastern Europe. In these debates, some of the early commentators argued that class inequalities in central and eastern Europe were less prominent (e.g., Ossowski 1963;Wesolowski [1966] 1977), others proposed class schemes that took into account the putatively special features of class systems in central and eastern Europe (e.g., Parkin 1971;Lipset and Dobson 1973;Konrad and Szelenyi 1979;Strmiska 1987;Kolosi 1988), and yet others asserted that processes of industrialization and modernization produced occupational and status structures similar to those in established market economies (Kerr 1983;Hoffman and Laird 1982). The latter position has considerable evidence behind it.…”
Section: Data and Measuresmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This revised version, known as the Featherman-Jones-Hauser hypothesis, has been supported by Erikson et al (1982), McRoberts and Selbee (1981), Hope (1982), Portocarero (1983), Häuser (1983), Grusky and Hauser (1984), 4 Erikson and Goldthorpe (1987a, 1987b, 1988a, and Jones and Davis (1986). The findings of these researchers 5 seem to suggest a large 3 For a discussion of the 'Six competing laws of motion' see Kerr (1983) and Lipset and Zetterberg (1966). 4 Grusky and Häuser, for instance, conclude their reanalysis of the Hazelrigg and Gamier data with the statement that "not only one simple model, quasi-perfect mobility, fit all of these data satisfactorily, but its coefficients do not vary greatly between countries.…”
Section: Cross-national Research On Mobility Patternsmentioning
confidence: 98%