2001
DOI: 10.1007/bf01670009
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Strength of the social dilemma in a public goods experiment: An exploration of the error hypothesis

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1

Citation Types

2
27
0

Year Published

2006
2006
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
8

Relationship

1
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 21 publications
(29 citation statements)
references
References 15 publications
2
27
0
Order By: Relevance
“…The results of the present paper also hold when preferences are captured by quadratic utility functions: Uixi,xi,x̂i=αiwxi()wixi2+βixi+xivi2()xitruex̂i2.This family of functions, which allows for a dominant strategy equilibrium with strictly positive contributions, has been documented in the experimental literature by relatively few papers (Keser , Willinger and Ziegelmeyer , Bracht, Figuières, and Ratto ).…”
supporting
confidence: 71%
“…The results of the present paper also hold when preferences are captured by quadratic utility functions: Uixi,xi,x̂i=αiwxi()wixi2+βixi+xivi2()xitruex̂i2.This family of functions, which allows for a dominant strategy equilibrium with strictly positive contributions, has been documented in the experimental literature by relatively few papers (Keser , Willinger and Ziegelmeyer , Bracht, Figuières, and Ratto ).…”
supporting
confidence: 71%
“…Interior equilibrium designs show that not all contributions are errors (Sefton and Steinberg, 1996;Isaac and Walker, 1998;Willinger and Ziegelmeyer, 2001). Designs which compare play against computers with that against people indicate that the error rate may nonetheless be substantial (Kurzban and Houser, 2001;Houser and Kurzban, 2002;Ferraro et al, 2003) investigate motivational heterogeneity, in a game where subjects repeatedly make a provisional decision then respond to the putative aggregate contribution, with the process terminating at random.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 98%
“…The return on contributions to the public good depended on one's own contributions and those by the other group members. To limit the risk that players get stuck in corner solutions where potential corruption (or any other intervention) could not show much effect, we used a non‐linear contribution mechanism (Keser, ; Willinger and Ziegelmeyer, ; Fenig et al ., ) that leads to interior solutions for any behavior between best‐response play and efficiency. Specifically, we use a quadratic return function for contributions to the public good:gi=gfalse(xi+Xifalse)=1Nfalse(a(XC)bfalse(XCfalse)2false), where X:=normalΣi=1Nxi denotes total contributions and X ‐ i : = Σ k ≠ i x k .…”
Section: Experimental Designmentioning
confidence: 99%