2009
DOI: 10.1509/jmkr.46.5.693
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Specifying Price Judgments with Range–Frequency Theory in Models of Brand Choice

Abstract: To construct a price judgment, consumers compare a focal price with one or more reference prices. However, reference price operationalizations in the brand choice literature use single-point summary measures that cannot account for several distributional effects. To account for effects beyond the first moment of the reference price distribution, the authors specify price judgments in models of brand choice in accordance with range–frequency theory. The findings indicate that range–frequency price judgments pro… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
42
0

Year Published

2013
2013
2015
2015

Publication Types

Select...
5
3

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 52 publications
(42 citation statements)
references
References 38 publications
0
42
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Price is a complex variable that can exert a dual role by increasing both perceptions of monetary sacrifice and perceptions of quality (Erickson & Johansson, 1985;Leavitt, 1954;Rao & Monroe, 1988). Moreover, usually price is not assessed as an isolated item but in comparison with either a reference price or a price distribution, such as the endpoint prices of the brand portfolio (Niedrich, Sharma, & Wedell, 2001;Niedrich, Weathers, Hill, & Bell, 2009). In the specific case of vertical extensions, we could expect that consumers assess the congruency between the price of the new product and the price-quality image of the parent brand rather than the price itself (Michel & Salha, 2005).…”
Section: Price (Discount Size)mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Price is a complex variable that can exert a dual role by increasing both perceptions of monetary sacrifice and perceptions of quality (Erickson & Johansson, 1985;Leavitt, 1954;Rao & Monroe, 1988). Moreover, usually price is not assessed as an isolated item but in comparison with either a reference price or a price distribution, such as the endpoint prices of the brand portfolio (Niedrich, Sharma, & Wedell, 2001;Niedrich, Weathers, Hill, & Bell, 2009). In the specific case of vertical extensions, we could expect that consumers assess the congruency between the price of the new product and the price-quality image of the parent brand rather than the price itself (Michel & Salha, 2005).…”
Section: Price (Discount Size)mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…However, the implications of the rank-based models have not been explored within the literature on food evaluation or within the marketing and consumer research literature more generally (although see Niedrich et al, 2001;Niedrich et al, 2009). In these literatures, the reference level account still predominates.…”
Section: Social Norms and Rank-based Nudgingmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Equation (1) does not have a separate price term, as it is not jointly identified with the ERP gain-loss components (Briesch et al 1997;Moon et al 2006;Niedrich et al 2009). …”
Section: Loss Aversion Asymmetrymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…However, extant reference price studies indicate that IRP is shaped by a substantially larger number of past purchase occasions (Briesch et al 1997;Niedrich et al 2009). Under these more realistic circumstances, the gap between the brand's price and its IRP is not only the result of the frequency of price increases versus decreases but is the net effect of both the frequency and magnitude.…”
Section: Condition 2: Brand Prices Increase Over Timementioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation