1997
DOI: 10.1111/1467-6435.00015
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Social Insurance Based on Personal Savings Accounts: A Possible Reform Strategy for Overburdened Welfare States

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
17
0

Year Published

1998
1998
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
6
2

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 24 publications
(17 citation statements)
references
References 2 publications
0
17
0
Order By: Relevance
“…14 Bergh (2005) calculates that 75% of all redistributive transfers in Sweden concern life cycle redistributions for the same individual. Large part of such transfers can be handled in other ways, notably by private agents or through mandatory personal savings accounts (Fölster 1997 Disincentive effects of a large government sector will set in sooner or later, and according to many observers such effects were apparent in both countries by the mid 1970s, but severe structural crises were required before relative government spending was lowered. 16 Since the early to mid 1990s there has been a great deal of deregulation of product markets, and globalization has strongly increased the competitive pressure both on firms and tax bases (Sinn 1998;Bergh and Karlsson 2010).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…14 Bergh (2005) calculates that 75% of all redistributive transfers in Sweden concern life cycle redistributions for the same individual. Large part of such transfers can be handled in other ways, notably by private agents or through mandatory personal savings accounts (Fölster 1997 Disincentive effects of a large government sector will set in sooner or later, and according to many observers such effects were apparent in both countries by the mid 1970s, but severe structural crises were required before relative government spending was lowered. 16 Since the early to mid 1990s there has been a great deal of deregulation of product markets, and globalization has strongly increased the competitive pressure both on firms and tax bases (Sinn 1998;Bergh and Karlsson 2010).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In fact, one in five had moved up at least two quintiles. 4 Studies from several welfare states indicate that as little as 20 to 25 percent of social transfers may actually redistribute between individuals, while the remaining 75 to 80 percent merely smoothes income over the individual's life cycle (Hussénius and Sélen 1994;Fölster 1998). The taxes that need to be levied to finance these transfers inevitably distort economic incentives, reducing the incentive to work, save and invest.…”
Section: The Basic Principles Behind Welfare Accountsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…A system of drawing rights, finally, would allow the individual to draw on an account in the public sector for well-defined contingencies, for instance, in connection with education, training, sickness or unemployment, though less would then be available later on, ultimately for pensions (Fölster, 1995). An advantage of such a system, if it is made strongly actuarial'…”
Section: Rad/cal Reformsmentioning
confidence: 99%