1991
DOI: 10.1016/0749-5978(91)90013-j
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Reversal of the preference reversal phenomenon

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

1
30
0

Year Published

1991
1991
2013
2013

Publication Types

Select...
8

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 36 publications
(31 citation statements)
references
References 29 publications
1
30
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Such experiments have produced mixed results, but asymmetric PR is generally less pronounced than in WTA experiments, and sometimes is not present at all. It seems that WTP treatments tend to reduce the frequency of standard reversals and to increase the frequency of non-standard ones (Lichtenstein and Slovic 1971;Knez and Smith 1987;Casey 1991). These findings are compatible with the hypothesis that PR is the product of several causal mechanisms, at least one of which is in some way linked to WTA valuations.…”
Section: Discussionsupporting
confidence: 79%
“…Such experiments have produced mixed results, but asymmetric PR is generally less pronounced than in WTA experiments, and sometimes is not present at all. It seems that WTP treatments tend to reduce the frequency of standard reversals and to increase the frequency of non-standard ones (Lichtenstein and Slovic 1971;Knez and Smith 1987;Casey 1991). These findings are compatible with the hypothesis that PR is the product of several causal mechanisms, at least one of which is in some way linked to WTA valuations.…”
Section: Discussionsupporting
confidence: 79%
“…In an attempt to equalize the choice frequency across gamble types, Casey (1991Casey ( , 1994) created significant differences in the expected values of the bets in each pair. In these papers, there are four otherwise comparable data sets, two with incentives and two without: Casey (1991) experiment 2, large bets and experiment 2, small bets; and Casey (1994) large stakes bets and small stakes bets.…”
Section: Additional Evidencementioning
confidence: 99%
“…The experiments in the literature have mostly considered hypothetical gambles for money. In general, no substantial difference was found between hypothetical gambles and gambles in which participants are actually paid according to their choices (Casey, 1991;Grether & Plott, 1979;Lichtenstein & Slovic, 1973;Mellers, Chang, Birnbaum, & Ord6fiez, 1992;Pommerehne, Schneider, & Zweifel, 1982;Slovic, 1975, Experiment 3;Tversky & Kalaneman, 1992); an exception is Bohm (1994).…”
Section: Possible Objections To Our Findingsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In the choosing task, (10, 5 Migr) was preferred to (20, 5 Migr), but in the matching task, the participant assigned a higher value to (20, 5 Migr) than to (10, 5 Migr). Traditional preference reversals (Beattie & Baron, 1991;Bimbaum et al, 1992;Bostic, Herrnstein, & Luce, 1990;Casey, 1991;Cho, Luce, & yon Winterfeldt, 1994;Delquit, 1993;Fischer & Hawkins, 1993;Fischhoff et al, 1980;Goldstein & Einhorn, 1987;Gonz,~iles-Vallejo & Wallsten, 1992;Grether & Plott, 1979;Hawkins, 1994;Hershey & Schoemaker, 1985;Johnson & Schkade, 1989;Lichtenstein & Slovic, 1971;Lichtenstein & Slovic, 1973;Lindman, 1971;Loomes et al, 1989;Mellers, Chang, et al, 1992;Mellers, Ord6fiez, & Birnbaum, 1992;Pommerehne et al, 1982;Slovic, 1975;Slovic et al, 1990;Slovic & Lichtenstein, 1983;Tversky et al, 1988;Tversky et al, 1990) occur when stimuli are compared for more than one attribute, and they have been explained mostly by changes in the weighting with which the attributes are combined in different tasks. This explanation cannot be applied to our findings.…”
Section: Implications Of Our Findingsmentioning
confidence: 99%