2012
DOI: 10.1007/s10107-012-0558-3
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

On the solution of affine generalized Nash equilibrium problems with shared constraints by Lemke’s method

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
4
1

Citation Types

0
23
0

Year Published

2013
2013
2016
2016

Publication Types

Select...
5
1

Relationship

1
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 38 publications
(23 citation statements)
references
References 46 publications
0
23
0
Order By: Relevance
“…A third consequence is that any z ∈ SOL (q, M) having |σ (z)| > s, i.e., more than s positive components, will be elusive in the sense that it cannot be computed by LS1 applied to (q, d, M) where d is an extended s-step vector. (The reader is referred to a recent paper [19] where it is demonstrated that LS1 can only compute solutions with a particular property of the LCP formulation of a generalized Nash equilibrium problem; such problems provide a class of realistic LCPs where many solutions are elusive when they are solved by LS1.) A fourth consequence of Theorem 1 is that all matrices M ∈ SP must belong to the class Q, which is to say that for every q, the LCP (q, M) has at least one solution.…”
Section: A New Matrix Class Spmentioning
confidence: 98%
“…A third consequence is that any z ∈ SOL (q, M) having |σ (z)| > s, i.e., more than s positive components, will be elusive in the sense that it cannot be computed by LS1 applied to (q, d, M) where d is an extended s-step vector. (The reader is referred to a recent paper [19] where it is demonstrated that LS1 can only compute solutions with a particular property of the LCP formulation of a generalized Nash equilibrium problem; such problems provide a class of realistic LCPs where many solutions are elusive when they are solved by LS1.) A fourth consequence of Theorem 1 is that all matrices M ∈ SP must belong to the class Q, which is to say that for every q, the LCP (q, M) has at least one solution.…”
Section: A New Matrix Class Spmentioning
confidence: 98%
“…The closest setting is the one of affine generalized Nash equilibrium problems (AGNEPs), where GNEPs with linear constraints and quadratic cost functions are considered, which are convex in the player variables. This setting was introduced explicitly in [6] and also investigated in [7,8]. Various examples of GNEPs where players share affine constraints are summarized in [6].…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 98%
“…This setting was introduced explicitly in [6] and also investigated in [7,8]. Various examples of GNEPs where players share affine constraints are summarized in [6]. Furthermore, the very common case of players having finite strategy sets and minimizing their expected losses, allowing mixed strategies, yields special LGNEPs (cf.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 98%
“…We already gave some references of works related to ours with respect to the linear complementarity. The work by Schiro et al [20] is one of them and deals actually with a more general problem as ours. However, the termination criterion for their algorithm is quite technical and it does not seem to be possible to prove that their algorithm terminates for sure on a equilibrium.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In 1965, Lemke [14] designed a pivoting algorithm for solving a linear complementarity problem under a quite general form. This algorithm has been adapted and extended several times -see for instance Adler and Verma [1], Asmuth et al [3], Cottle et al [6], Schiro et al [20] to be able to deal with linear complementarity problems that do not directly fit in the required framework of the original Lemke algorithm.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%