1986
DOI: 10.1080/00036848600000063
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

On the shock-absorption view of money: international evidence from the 1960s and 1970s

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

0
5
0

Year Published

1988
1988
2003
2003

Publication Types

Select...
7

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 12 publications
(6 citation statements)
references
References 13 publications
0
5
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Inherent in this kind of framework is the notion that it may be in the individual's interest not to make instantaneous adjustments to money balances as a result of the time required for searching behaviour (Kannianen and Tarkka, 1986), or because of high costs of adjustment in the short run (Cuthbertson and Taylor, 1987b). Minimising the costs of adjustment may lead the individual to conclude that there is an incentive occasionally to do nothing towards the actual process of adjustment in the short run (see Cabellero and Engel, 1991, BenIlan and Blinder, 1992).…”
Section: Microfoundations Of Buffer Stock Modelsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Inherent in this kind of framework is the notion that it may be in the individual's interest not to make instantaneous adjustments to money balances as a result of the time required for searching behaviour (Kannianen and Tarkka, 1986), or because of high costs of adjustment in the short run (Cuthbertson and Taylor, 1987b). Minimising the costs of adjustment may lead the individual to conclude that there is an incentive occasionally to do nothing towards the actual process of adjustment in the short run (see Cabellero and Engel, 1991, BenIlan and Blinder, 1992).…”
Section: Microfoundations Of Buffer Stock Modelsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“… Variations on this model due to Kannianen and Tarkka (1986) allow for a low adjustment process to account for the search time required to make wise investment decisions which are more difficult to reverse in less liquid assets. …”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Table 2. Potential Variables and Their Predicted Signs Following D. Hendry's general-to-specific approach (see, e.g., Hendry (1979) and Gilbert (1986)), we started for each of the three equations from the following unrestricted model: 2/ I/ The buffer stock and disequilibrium money approaches also link short-term money demand to credit market conditions (for an overview, see, e.g., Andersen (1985) and for an application, see, e.g., Kanniainen and Tarkka (1986), but under different assumptions. These approaches assume that disequilibrium in credit markets is reflected in the first place in holdings of money and/or liquid assets.…”
Section: And the Country's International Reserve Position (Ir) Variab...mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The shock absorber literature, e.g. Carr and Darby (1981), MacKinnon and Milbourne (1984), Carr, Darby and Thornton (1985), Cuthbertson and Taylor (1986, 1988, Kanniainen and Tarkka (1986), Muscatelli (1988), concentrates on incorporating unanticipated shocks to the aggregate money supply in single-equation aggregate demand for money functions and, in general, ignores the potentially important subsequent spillover effects. The disequilibrium money models, e.g.…”
Section: Ftnancial Buffers In Sectoral Portfoliosmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Currie and Kenally (1985), for example, stress that the structure of adjustment costs across different financial instruments is important in determining the choice of financial buffers and costs of gathering information and 'entry fee'/financial service charges are likely to be different for different types of agents. Kanniainen and Tarkka (1986) also argue that payments processes and information constraints faced by different agents are likely to be different.…”
Section: Ftnancial Buffers In Sectoral Portfoliosmentioning
confidence: 99%