2012
DOI: 10.1007/s00712-012-0286-4
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

On hierarchical competition in oligopoly

Abstract: In this paper, we consider a hierarchical oligopoly model, in which firms compete on quantities of an homogeneous product. We provide a proof and an interpretation that under the three necessary and sufficient conditions of linear aggregate demand, constant and identical marginal costs, the strategy of leaders at any stage depends neither on the number of leaders who play after nor on the number of remaining stages. So, all firms behave as Cournotian oligopolists on the residual demand. We show that these thre… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

2
4
0

Year Published

2014
2014
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
5
1

Relationship

0
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 10 publications
(6 citation statements)
references
References 11 publications
2
4
0
Order By: Relevance
“…We can use Taylor's theorem to express g(X) = [α − r g (X)](1 − X), where the remainder 49 For example, in the Stackelberg oligopoly with linear demand, the leader's quantity is independent of the number of followers. This observation has been made before, for example by Anderson and Engers (1992); Julien et al (2012). In fact, Julien et al (2012) derived this equilibrium characterization for arbitrary sequential oligopolies with linear demand (which implies α = 1 here).…”
Section: H Large Contestssupporting
confidence: 53%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…We can use Taylor's theorem to express g(X) = [α − r g (X)](1 − X), where the remainder 49 For example, in the Stackelberg oligopoly with linear demand, the leader's quantity is independent of the number of followers. This observation has been made before, for example by Anderson and Engers (1992); Julien et al (2012). In fact, Julien et al (2012) derived this equilibrium characterization for arbitrary sequential oligopolies with linear demand (which implies α = 1 here).…”
Section: H Large Contestssupporting
confidence: 53%
“…For example, in the Stackelberg oligopoly with linear demand, the leader's quantity is independent of the number of followers. This observation has been made before, for example by Anderson and Engers (1992);Julien et al (2012). In fact,Julien et al (2012) derived this equilibrium characterization for arbitrary sequential oligopolies with linear demand (which implies α = 1 here).50 Equivalently, it is identical to n n in the first T − 1 periods, but all remaining players are collected into period T .…”
mentioning
confidence: 63%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…This compares to Boyer and Moreaux [8], who study a Stackelberg game and show that production of each firm solely depends on the rank of the firm and not on the number of firms in the market. Julien et al [11] find a similar result in a multistage Stackelberg game with multiple firms in each stage. Output decisions in each stage only depend on the previous output decisions but do not depend on the number of followers or following periods.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 69%
“…The model has been later used and extended by Anderson and Engers [1992]; Pal and Sarkar [2001]; Lafay [2010]; Julien et al . [2011, 2012]; and Ino and Matsumura [2012] to cover more than two periods and an arbitrary number of firms in each period. In all those papers, the model has the Stackelberg independence property.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%