2017
DOI: 10.1016/j.econlet.2017.03.020
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Linking individual and collective contests through noise level and sharing rules

Abstract: We propose the use of Nitzan’s (1991) sharing rule in collective contests as a tractable way of modelling individual contests. This proposal (i) tractably introduces noise in Tullock contests when no closed form solution in pure strategies exists, (ii) satisfies the important property of homogeneity of degree zero, (iii) can be effort or noise equivalent to a standard Tullock contest

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

0
6
0

Year Published

2018
2018
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
8

Relationship

3
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 10 publications
(6 citation statements)
references
References 36 publications
0
6
0
Order By: Relevance
“…9 The campaign stage for impressionable voters is resolved via Tullock's ratio-form CSF that facilitates the comparative statics of our model. In the symmetric case, our results would have the same qualitative features if we considered the difference-form CSF proposed by Alcalde and Dahm (2007), the tractable noise CSF proposed by Amegashie (2006) or the relative-difference CSF by Beviá and Corchón (2015) under the parameter restrictions proposed by Balart, Chowdhury, and Troumpounis (2017). and impressionable with ex-ante probability 1 − F (y).…”
Section: Modelmentioning
confidence: 52%
“…9 The campaign stage for impressionable voters is resolved via Tullock's ratio-form CSF that facilitates the comparative statics of our model. In the symmetric case, our results would have the same qualitative features if we considered the difference-form CSF proposed by Alcalde and Dahm (2007), the tractable noise CSF proposed by Amegashie (2006) or the relative-difference CSF by Beviá and Corchón (2015) under the parameter restrictions proposed by Balart, Chowdhury, and Troumpounis (2017). and impressionable with ex-ante probability 1 − F (y).…”
Section: Modelmentioning
confidence: 52%
“…The parameter r is often interpreted as the returns to scale from effort (Perez-Castrillo and Verdier, 1992; Baye, Kovenock, and De Vries, 1994;Nti, 1999): r > 1 indicating increasing returns and r < 1 indicating decreasing returns. We interpret r as the noise in the CSF (Amegashie, 2006;Jia, 2008;Balart, Chowdhury, and Troumpounis, 2017). Setting r = 0 implies that the contest outcome is completely random and independent of individual effort levels; when r = 1, the contest takes the form of a raffle or lottery, and when r = ∞, an all-pay auction is staged.…”
Section: Mechanism 1: Choice Of the Csfmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The parameter r is often interpreted as the returns to scale from effort (Baye et al, 1994;Nti, 1999;Perez-Castrillo & Verdier, 1992): r > 1 indicating increasing returns and r < 1 denoting decreasing returns. Alternatively, r is interpreted as the noise in the CSF (Amegashie, 2006;Balart et al, 2017;Jia, 2008) and this is the interpretation we follow. Setting r = 0 implies that the contest outcome is completely random and independent of individual effort levels; when r = 1, the contest takes the form of a raffle or lottery (L), and when r ¼ ∞, it characterizes an APA.…”
Section: Mechanism 1: Choice Of the Csfmentioning
confidence: 93%
“…The parameter r is often interpreted as the returns to scale from effort (Perez-Castrillo and Verdier, 1992;Baye, Kovenock, and De Vries, 1994;Nti, 1999): r > 1 indicating increasing returns and r < 1 indicating decreasing returns. We interpret r as the noise in the CSF (Amegashie, 2006;Jia, 2008;Balart, Chowdhury, and Troumpounis, 2017). Setting r = 0 implies that the contest outcome is completely random and independent of individual effort levels; when r = 1, the contest takes the form of a raffle or lottery, and when r = ∞, an all-pay auction is staged.…”
Section: Mechanism 1: Choice Of the Csfmentioning
confidence: 99%