1999
DOI: 10.1111/j.1574-0862.1999.tb00566.x
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Least‐cost cheap‐food policies: some implications of international food aid

Abstract: Many low‐income countries pursue cheap‐food policies in which consumers pay subsidized prices for bread, rice and other staples. This paper addresses the issue of why different governments select different food subsidy policies, using multiple instruments rather than a simple across‐the‐board subsidy to provide consumers with access to cheap food. It examines the optimal structure of cheap‐food policies in the context of a partial equilibrium model in which the country may he large in trade, and is able to com… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1

Citation Types

0
2
0

Year Published

2003
2003
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
4

Relationship

1
3

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 4 publications
(2 citation statements)
references
References 20 publications
0
2
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Examples include the credit programs offered by France and other European countries for sales of wheat and other crops to low income countries up to the late 1990s and the U.S. GSM 102 and 103 credit programs, also targeted to developing countries (Smith & Goodwin, 2001). Nonemergency food aid programs, in which the donor country ships domestically produced food to other countries, also fall into this category because essentially these are exports offered with a 100% subsidy (Alston, Smith, Acquaye, & Hosseini, 1999). Although export subsidy programs tend to increase prices in a country's domestic markets, 5 The WTO Nairobi Package would impose new disciplines on export credits (capping the maximum repayment period to18 months), food aid (must be needs-driven, provided in fully grant form, and not tied to commercial agricultural exports or other goods and services), and agricultural-exporting State Trading Enterprises.…”
Section: Export Competition and Export Restriction Programsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Examples include the credit programs offered by France and other European countries for sales of wheat and other crops to low income countries up to the late 1990s and the U.S. GSM 102 and 103 credit programs, also targeted to developing countries (Smith & Goodwin, 2001). Nonemergency food aid programs, in which the donor country ships domestically produced food to other countries, also fall into this category because essentially these are exports offered with a 100% subsidy (Alston, Smith, Acquaye, & Hosseini, 1999). Although export subsidy programs tend to increase prices in a country's domestic markets, 5 The WTO Nairobi Package would impose new disciplines on export credits (capping the maximum repayment period to18 months), food aid (must be needs-driven, provided in fully grant form, and not tied to commercial agricultural exports or other goods and services), and agricultural-exporting State Trading Enterprises.…”
Section: Export Competition and Export Restriction Programsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Centralised authority was generally dismissed as disingenuous; governments had simultaneously leveraged their involvement in staple food markets into working political capital (Bates 1981). Marketing boards were used to both tax agriculture, and maintain cheap food prices in urban areas to avoid civil unrest and garner favour among key political allies (Sanders et al 1996; Alston et al 1999). Such urban bias has contributed to the agriculture stagnation that has occurred in several countries, leaving rural areas underdeveloped (see the discussion in Duncan and Jones 1993).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%