Market Imperfections and Macroeconomic Dynamics 2002
DOI: 10.1007/978-1-4757-3598-7_4
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Inflation and Productivity Differentials in EMU

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
11
0

Year Published

2003
2003
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
7

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 16 publications
(11 citation statements)
references
References 18 publications
0
11
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Our basic version of the Balassa‐Samuelson model is a two‐country model, with a tradable goods (industry) sector and a non‐tradable goods (services) sector, as described by De Grauwe and Skudelny (2002). We assume perfect competition in the tradable goods markets and perfect mobility in the national labour markets – but no labour mobility between the two countries.…”
Section: The Balassa‐samuelson Effect With Respect To Emu Accessionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Our basic version of the Balassa‐Samuelson model is a two‐country model, with a tradable goods (industry) sector and a non‐tradable goods (services) sector, as described by De Grauwe and Skudelny (2002). We assume perfect competition in the tradable goods markets and perfect mobility in the national labour markets – but no labour mobility between the two countries.…”
Section: The Balassa‐samuelson Effect With Respect To Emu Accessionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Unlike DeGrauwe and Skudelny (2000), whose time series span the period 1970-1995, we view the closeness of the period examined to the presence as being more important than the length of the time series given structural breaks and the limited comparability of data as one goes further back in time.…”
mentioning
confidence: 97%
“…() collects estimates for that part of inflation that can directly be related to the Balassa‐Samuelson with data samples covered by the different papers ranging from 1960 to 2002. For Ireland, the average estimate is 2.6 per cent, for Spain 1.9 per cent, for Italy and Greece it is 1.9 and 1.7 per cent, respectively, and for Portugal the estimate is as low as 0.8 per cent (see also De Grauwe and Skudelny, ). This indicates that a fraction of inflation rates is accounted for by the Balassa‐Samuelson effect and can thus be assumed to soften the growth‐harming effect of high inflation.…”
Section: Inflation and Growth In Europe: An Empirical Analysismentioning
confidence: 97%