2012
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1738531
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Incentives in a Stage-Gate Process

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

1
23
0

Year Published

2015
2015
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
7

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 18 publications
(24 citation statements)
references
References 43 publications
1
23
0
Order By: Relevance
“…In particular, the marginal effort cost at zero is zero, which implies that the contractor need not entail a loss without the effort invested to complete the project. This assumption is in accordance with the practical fact, which has been used in Chao al. (2014) and Yang et al (2014) and implies increasing marginal cost of effort.…”
Section: Notations and Assumptionssupporting
confidence: 82%
“…In particular, the marginal effort cost at zero is zero, which implies that the contractor need not entail a loss without the effort invested to complete the project. This assumption is in accordance with the practical fact, which has been used in Chao al. (2014) and Yang et al (2014) and implies increasing marginal cost of effort.…”
Section: Notations and Assumptionssupporting
confidence: 82%
“…This stream of work focuses on various types of agency problems in an inter-organizational innovation context, such as moral hazard (Bhaskaran and Krishnan, 2009), adverse selection (Crama et al, 2016), and holdup problem (Bhattacharya et al, 2015). The innovation problem context is also modeled differently, varying on aspects such as intra-versus inter-organizational innovation (Bhaskaran and Krishnan, 2009;Chao et al, 2014), single versus multiple suppliers (Che and Gale, 2003;Wang and Shin, 2015), single versus multiple stages (Chao et al, 2014;Rahmani et al, 2016), the party with the decision right (buyer versus supplier) (Agrawal and Oraiopoulos, 2016), and the types of uncertainty considered (market versus project) (Savva and Scholtes, 2014). Finally, the literature also examines various types of contracts, such as revenue-sharing (Savva and Scholtes, 2014), renegotiation (Plambeck and Taylor, 2007), and milestone/delaying contracts (Bhattacharya et al, 2015).…”
Section: Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…First, complexity often emerges from the size of the NPD project where it relates to the number of technologies, components or functions being developed (Chapman & Hyland, 2004;Griffin, 1997a;Kim & Wilemon, 2003;Nightingale, 2000) and to the number of organisations or business functions that are involved in the project (Dougherty, 2017;Kim & Wilemon, 2003). Second, complexity stems from the nature of the development activities, such as the number of different development tasks and their interdependence (Ahmad et al, 2013;Chapman & Hyland, 2004;Dooley & Van de Ven, 1999;McCarthy et al, 2006), as well as the novelty of these tasks (Chao et al, 2014;Maggitti, Smith, & Katila, 2013;Tatikonda & Rosenthal, 2000).…”
Section: Complexity Of Npd Processesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…To understand the complexity of NPD projects, existing studies have analysed the properties of the system involved in NPD projects (Dooley & Van de Ven, 1999;McCarthy, Tsinopoulos, Allen, & Rose-Anderssen, 2006;Mihm, Loch, & Huchzermeier, 2003), outlined how to design NPD processes to handle complexity (Chao, Lichtendahl, & Grushka-Cockayne, 2014;Iansiti & MacCormack, 1997) and unravelled practices that individuals and companies use to manage complexity (Chapman & Hyland, 2004;Dunne & Dougherty, 2016;Griffin, 1997a). Yet, prior research has not been able to put forward an approach that would capture the causal complexity (e.g., Misangyi et al, 2017) inherent in the NPD processes.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%