2016
DOI: 10.1086/685378
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Holding Individual Representatives Accountable: The Role of Electoral Systems

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1

Citation Types

2
27
1
3

Year Published

2017
2017
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
4
4

Relationship

1
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 44 publications
(33 citation statements)
references
References 42 publications
2
27
1
3
Order By: Relevance
“…Even if the reservation value of most voters was small in most cases, shocks that affect voter preferences (and hence their reservation value) can more readily translate into representation that is in line with voter preferences under a PLPR system in which voters follow a satisficing with rank-taking logic (compared to closed lists). While the analyses in this paper cannot say to which extent voters rate candidates on different grounds than parties, findings from other studies show that voters do use PLPR systems to punish candidates they associate with misconduct (Rudolph and Däubler 2016) or a low-regarded ruling elite (Stegmaier et al 2014). Perhaps preference voting in list systems rather has the character of a veto or correction device, with strong manifestations only visible in rather exceptional 36 Also note that parties may do this only because lists are not closed, and having the original order overturned may imply reputation costs.…”
Section: Resultscontrasting
confidence: 59%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…Even if the reservation value of most voters was small in most cases, shocks that affect voter preferences (and hence their reservation value) can more readily translate into representation that is in line with voter preferences under a PLPR system in which voters follow a satisficing with rank-taking logic (compared to closed lists). While the analyses in this paper cannot say to which extent voters rate candidates on different grounds than parties, findings from other studies show that voters do use PLPR systems to punish candidates they associate with misconduct (Rudolph and Däubler 2016) or a low-regarded ruling elite (Stegmaier et al 2014). Perhaps preference voting in list systems rather has the character of a veto or correction device, with strong manifestations only visible in rather exceptional 36 Also note that parties may do this only because lists are not closed, and having the original order overturned may imply reputation costs.…”
Section: Resultscontrasting
confidence: 59%
“…This latter finding adds to the evidence for the satisficing-with-rank-taking model, as further discussed in the main text. Table A.5: Effects of moving up one rank by rank and by omitted first versus any subsequent baseline list position (as reported in Figure 1) ( (Rudolph and Däubler 2016;Kauder and Potrafke 2015), and urbanity. Results show no evidence that the distribution function of the list ranks of candidates in a district differs by these observable characteristics.…”
Section: A4 Additional Specifications For Main Modelsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Our study is different in that it looks at whether scandals affect how voters react to politicians who belong to the same social group as the scandalous politicians. Our findings add to recent results suggesting that scandals exert only modest effects on voting in subsequent elections (e.g., Basinger, ; Eggers, ; Rudolph & Däubler, ; Vivyan, Wagner, & Tarlov, ).…”
supporting
confidence: 86%
“…Die Grenzen der Wahlrechtsreform in parlamentarischen Regierungssystemen bilden schon seit längerem die Basis für die Rechtfertigung präsidentieller Regierungssysteme (vgl. Shugart und Carey 1992;Mainwaring und Shugart 1997;Cheibub 2006 Präsidentielle Regierungssysteme bringen aber den Nachteil mit sich, exekutive Macht stark in einer einzelnen Person zu konzentrieren (Linz 1994; (Rudolph und Däubler 2016).…”
Section: Semi-parlamentarische Reformoptionenunclassified