2019
DOI: 10.1007/s00199-019-01211-w
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Global gains from reduction in trade costs

Abstract: We derive a simple equation to calculate the global welfare impact of the simultaneous reduction of trade costs between multiple country-pairs. Interestingly, we …nd that we obtain the same equation for a broad class of trade models. Moreover, balanced trade is mostly not required for the equation to work, nor does trade elasticity need to be known. The global welfare impact only depends on two sets of statistics: (i) the ratio of bilateral trade ‡ow between each pair of trading partners and global income; and… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

1
4
0

Year Published

2020
2020
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
6
1

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 9 publications
(5 citation statements)
references
References 43 publications
1
4
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Therefore, consistent with studies such as by Lai, Fan, and Qi (2015), the welfare e¤ects of a change in trade costs (in percentage terms) depend on the weighted average of the percentage changes in bilateral trade costs, where weights are bilateral expenditure shares. As is evident, the right hand side of Equation 16 also considers changes in preferences, which is important to capture welfare changes due to the e¤ects of distance on preferences versus on trade costs as in studies such as by Hummels and Schaur (2013) or Yilmazkuday (2016).…”
Section: The Gains From Tradesupporting
confidence: 80%
“…Therefore, consistent with studies such as by Lai, Fan, and Qi (2015), the welfare e¤ects of a change in trade costs (in percentage terms) depend on the weighted average of the percentage changes in bilateral trade costs, where weights are bilateral expenditure shares. As is evident, the right hand side of Equation 16 also considers changes in preferences, which is important to capture welfare changes due to the e¤ects of distance on preferences versus on trade costs as in studies such as by Hummels and Schaur (2013) or Yilmazkuday (2016).…”
Section: The Gains From Tradesupporting
confidence: 80%
“…Firms produce horizontally differentiated varieties within the industry under conditions of monopolistic competition. 3 The existence of fixed production costs implies that a firm drawing a productivity below the " zero-profit productivity cutoff " would make negative profits from producing and hence chooses instead to exit the industry. Fixed and variable costs of exporting ensure that only those active firms that draw a productivity above a higher "export productivity cutoff " find it profitable to export.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Each of these responses reallocates resources toward 2 See also and Melitz and Ottaviano (2008). 3 For alternative approaches to firm heterogeneity, see Bernard et al (2003) and Yeaple (2005). 4 While the original model focuses on exporting, this framework is extended to incorporate foreign direct investment (FDI) as an alternative mode for servicing foreign markets in Helpman, Melitz, and Yeaple (2004). high-productivity firms and raises aggregate productivity through a change in industry composition.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Various papers measure the first-order impact of changes in bilateral trade costs on world welfare(Atkeson and Burstein, 2010;Burstein and Cravino, 2015;Lai et al 2015; or in trade costs in specific links of a transport network on country-level welfare (Allen and Arkolakis, 2019) around an observed equilibrium. The right-hand side of (9) could be used for a similar purpose, given a specific set of changes in trade costs.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%