2010
DOI: 10.1016/j.forpol.2009.08.008
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Examining incentives for adjacent non-industrial private forest landowners to cooperate

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
15
0

Year Published

2012
2012
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
5
3

Relationship

1
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 26 publications
(15 citation statements)
references
References 15 publications
0
15
0
Order By: Relevance
“…In the United States, where 35 % of all forests are owned by individuals and families, social interactions can provide an understanding of the actors and information pathways shaping private forest management. Land use decisions by individuals, families, estates, and other unincorporated private entities (collectively known as family forest owners) affect the capacity of forest lands to sustain ecosystem benefits, and resist threats like fire and invasive species (Butler 2008;Vokoun et al 2010). It can be insightful to know whom family forest owners talk to and whom they turn to for advice related to the health and management of their woodlands.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In the United States, where 35 % of all forests are owned by individuals and families, social interactions can provide an understanding of the actors and information pathways shaping private forest management. Land use decisions by individuals, families, estates, and other unincorporated private entities (collectively known as family forest owners) affect the capacity of forest lands to sustain ecosystem benefits, and resist threats like fire and invasive species (Butler 2008;Vokoun et al 2010). It can be insightful to know whom family forest owners talk to and whom they turn to for advice related to the health and management of their woodlands.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Previous studies indicate that without strong and enforced regulations, or effective regulatory or market incentives, landowners are willing to retain remnant native woody vegetation if it is located on land unsuitable for pasture (Bradshaw et al, 1998;Wilson, 1992), and/or when there is significant private net benefit (Bradshaw et al, 1998;Fairweather, 1996;Mead, 1995;Rauniyar & Parker, 1998;Underwood & Ripley, 2000;Vokoun et al, 2010). The results of this study indicate many farmers do not believe woody vegetation provides sufficient benefit to offset its costs, particularly on productive pasture land.…”
Section: Are the Resulting Woody Vegetation Network Significantly Comentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Studies evaluating voluntary regulatory approaches for planting trees demonstrate landowner support for tree planting when they attribute sufficient private values to their products and services (e.g. Gyau et al, 2014;Underwood & Ripley, 2000;Vokoun, Amacher, Sullivan, & Wear, 2010). In New Zealand, studies indicate rangeland farmers value trees for sheltering stock, and in areas unsuitable for pasture (Bradshaw, Cocklin, & Smit, 1998;Wilson, 1992).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In these cases, missing markets and the under-provision of beneficial activities are caused by a variety of reasons. Spatial externalities can be hard to fully internalize without a policy intervention simply because of the prohibitive cost of arranging negotiations between multiple landowners and the large number of other affected parties [14,15]. Free riding incentives among adjacent landowners lead to under-provision of public goods across space, such as taking actions to reduce hazardous fuels [16].…”
Section: Sources Of Externalities In Forestrymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Despite this, cooperation across space may not be as feasible in a more traditional forest management context. There would be obvious transaction costs of forest landowners coordinating their actions, not the least of which is the fact that absentee ownership often comprises nearly 30 % of land ownership for nonindustrial private land in the USA (see [15]). The most common instrument in these situations to incentivize fuel reduction has therefore been more traditional cost-sharing programs (see [109]).…”
Section: Forest Fuel Reductionmentioning
confidence: 99%