2010
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1711198
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Electricity Network Tariff Architectures A Comparison of Four OECD Countries

Abstract: The study is motivated by the question "what is the optimal tariff design?" While we do not offer an answer to this question, we use the different designs in four select countries to illuminate the issues involved in designing electricity network tariffs. Electricity networks are a resource shared by all network users. A tariff design that is clear to network users and well understood by them can help them make efficient decisions. A design that sets up conflicting or perverse incentives results in economic di… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
2
1

Citation Types

0
26
0

Year Published

2012
2012
2020
2020

Publication Types

Select...
6
1

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 16 publications
(26 citation statements)
references
References 7 publications
0
26
0
Order By: Relevance
“…7 Sakhrani and Parsons (2010) analyze the network tariffs of four OECD countries in much detail; for both the EU member states included in their selection, Portugal and Spain, they find total access fees to be a mark-up on the power price paid by consumers that solely consist of price-independent capacity charges (e/kW/year, capacity constrains the power production, we finally suppose the two downstream generators to share the existing network units equally (Cremer and De Donder, 2013).…”
Section: The Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…7 Sakhrani and Parsons (2010) analyze the network tariffs of four OECD countries in much detail; for both the EU member states included in their selection, Portugal and Spain, they find total access fees to be a mark-up on the power price paid by consumers that solely consist of price-independent capacity charges (e/kW/year, capacity constrains the power production, we finally suppose the two downstream generators to share the existing network units equally (Cremer and De Donder, 2013).…”
Section: The Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For example, the New England system undertakes market efficiency upgrades (investments designed to reduce bulk system-wide costs) where the net present value of the reduction in system costs exceeds the net present value of the transmission investment; Sakhrani and Parsons [53].…”
Section: The Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…But this may be a mixed blessing; since expansion costs are nonlinear, incentives toward free riding can easily arise; Bushnell and Stoft [13]. The incentives to co-operate and undertake beneficial investments further depend on the business models adopted in different electricity markets (Wu et al [60]) and on network tariff architectures (Sakhrani and Parsons [53]). 6 There would be no further problem in using our model for a yearly period on an hourly basis (8,760 steps) apart from the increase in the time required for computation.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…One is connection charge for DG, which is paid by DG producers once when they require network access to compensate for the costs of connection. The other one is use-of-system (UoS) charge, which is paid by DG producers periodically to compensate the operation cost of network and capital expenses for new investment [32]. Who designs the tariffs and how the tariff structure should be designed depend on regulation.…”
Section: Network Tariff Designmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…To evaluate the reinforcement that may be required at different network levels a system impact study is usually conducted [32]. How the reinforcement cost caused by DG should be recovered depends on regulation.…”
Section: A Different Network Tariffsmentioning
confidence: 99%