2016
DOI: 10.1111/obes.12132
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Do Good Institutions Promote Countercyclical Macroeconomic Policies?

Abstract: The literature has argued that developing countries are unable to adopt countercyclical monetary and fiscal policies due to financial imperfections and unfavourable political-economy conditions. Using a world sample of up to 112 industrial and developing countries for 1984-2008, we find that the level of institutional quality plays a key role in countries' ability and willingness to implement countercyclical macroeconomic policies. Countries with strong (weak) institutions adopt countercyclical (procyclical) m… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

2
21
0
3

Year Published

2017
2017
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
8
1

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 47 publications
(26 citation statements)
references
References 38 publications
2
21
0
3
Order By: Relevance
“…This research therefore complements a recent body of empirical work comparing emerging/developing countries to developed countries, which incorporates institutional variables interacting with business cycles (the output gap) into both policy equations of deviations of either nominal interest rates from trend or real government spending, such as Calderón et al (2016). There is indeed a vast literature on institutions and economic policies, including Acemoglu et al (2003), Dollar and Kraay (2003), Bravo-Ortega and De Gregorio (2005), Loayza et al (2005), Zettelmeyer (2006), and Calderón and Fuentes (2012).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 82%
“…This research therefore complements a recent body of empirical work comparing emerging/developing countries to developed countries, which incorporates institutional variables interacting with business cycles (the output gap) into both policy equations of deviations of either nominal interest rates from trend or real government spending, such as Calderón et al (2016). There is indeed a vast literature on institutions and economic policies, including Acemoglu et al (2003), Dollar and Kraay (2003), Bravo-Ortega and De Gregorio (2005), Loayza et al (2005), Zettelmeyer (2006), and Calderón and Fuentes (2012).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 82%
“…For Institutional quality, 12 point ICRG's index is used for the calculation of a single index. ICRG's index for IQ is a comprehensive index also used by (Calderón, Duncan and Schmidt-Hebbel, 2016;Asif and Majid, 2018;Nawaz et al, 2018). As time-series data is used in this study and non-stationarity of the time series data is a serious issue, which may lead to spurious results.…”
Section: Data and Econometric Techniquesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Es posible que un país que en una fase expansiva ejerció un déficit o un superávit no correspondiente con las tasas de crecimiento se vea sujeto a seguir manteniendo su postura procíclica, como es el caso de países de bajos ingresos o en vías de desarrollo que no cuentan con un desarrollo institucional que permita el correcto manejo del gasto de acuerdo con el ciclo de la economía (Woo, 2009;Kaminsky et al, 2004;Calderón et al, 2016).…”
Section: Política Fiscal Y Ciclo Económicounclassified
“…No obstante, para algunos países resulta complicado, debido a su bajo desarrollo institucional que conlleva niveles significativos de deuda, débil estructura económica y política, problemas de corrupción, etc. (Calderón, Duncan y Schmidt-Hebbel, 2016), factores que impiden o limitan el margen de acción o bien los resultados requeridos. Según Tapsoba, Noumon y York (2017), la política fiscal procíclica podría estar explicada por deficiencias en materia de pronósticos causadas por la débil capacidad para realizarlos, aunado a la falta de datos y de capacidades técnicas.…”
Section: Introductionunclassified