2016
DOI: 10.1177/1354068816668669
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Do citizens vote for parties, policies or the expected winner in proportional representation systems? Evidence from four different countries using a multiple-type model

Abstract: This article presents a unified framework that allows us to disentangle to what extent agents in proportional representation (PR) systems engage in the different strategies that the available voting models have separately suggested: ‘party’, ‘coalitional’, ‘bandwagon’ and ‘other’ voting (i.e. neither of the previous three). Results using data from multiple countries reveal that at least 75% of agents cast a sincere party vote. Around 10% of voters try to affect policymaking by casting a coalitional vote. Since… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
4
1

Citation Types

1
5
0

Year Published

2018
2018
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
5

Relationship

3
2

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 6 publications
(6 citation statements)
references
References 32 publications
(68 reference statements)
1
5
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Strategic behavior seems to be modest. This is in line with previous findings that suggest that strategic behavior is not predominant among voters (Abramson et al, 2010;Alvarez et al, 2006;Blais et al, 2016;Hix et al, 2017;Riambau, 2016). 4 This could be explained by a variety of factors.…”
Section: Introductionsupporting
confidence: 92%
“…Strategic behavior seems to be modest. This is in line with previous findings that suggest that strategic behavior is not predominant among voters (Abramson et al, 2010;Alvarez et al, 2006;Blais et al, 2016;Hix et al, 2017;Riambau, 2016). 4 This could be explained by a variety of factors.…”
Section: Introductionsupporting
confidence: 92%
“…This distinguishes the bandwagon effect from strategic voting because the latter is initially motivated by the relative unpopularity of the initial preference – voters try to avoid ‘wasting’ their vote (Alvarez et al, 2006). If preferences align with popularity, then this vote-wasting logic need not lead to strategic voting – although some argue that strategic and sincere votes can be aligned (Riambau, 2016). If they do not align, then voters might use the information available to them to attempt to affect the election in a favourable way, and this can mean voting for a more popular party or candidate.…”
Section: Defining the Bandwagon Effectmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…It could be argued, of course, that distinguishing between strategic voting and the bandwagon effect is unnecessary. As intimated above, a simple reason this distinction is necessary is that strategic voting does not necessarily benefit more popular candidates or parties, especially in proportional representation systems where strategic voters might flock towards smaller parties who are likely to be included in a victorious coalition (Riambau, 2015, 2016), whereas bandwagoning does necessarily benefit more popular options. Equally, smaller parties might benefit from strategic voting in first-past-the-post single member district systems, because a given candidate has a good chance of winning a seat.…”
Section: Defining the Bandwagon Effectmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations