2003
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2482536
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Did the Great Inflation Occur Despite Policymaker Commitment to a Taylor Rule?

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

5
70
0

Year Published

2005
2005
2015
2015

Publication Types

Select...
9

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 57 publications
(75 citation statements)
references
References 21 publications
5
70
0
Order By: Relevance
“…6 In fact, we require only a small and quite natural deviation from rational expectations, based on the econometric learning approach increasingly utilized in macroeconomics. Recent applications include the design of monetary policy (Bullard and Mitra (2002), Evans and Honkapohja (2003), and Orphanides and Williams (2005a)), recurrent hyperinflations in Latin America (Marcet and Nicolini (2003)), US inflation and disinflation (Sargent (1999), Orphanides and Williams (2005b), Bullard and Eusepi (2005)), asset prices (Timmermann (1993), Brock and Hommes (1998), Bullard and Duffy (2001), 3 Fama (1984) demonstrates that, for this to happen, the variance of the risk premium must be greater than the variance of expected depreciation, and their covariance must be negative.These requirements do not appear to be supported empirically.…”
Section: U S D /G B P U S D /D E M U Sd /Jay G B P /D E M G B P /Jaymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…6 In fact, we require only a small and quite natural deviation from rational expectations, based on the econometric learning approach increasingly utilized in macroeconomics. Recent applications include the design of monetary policy (Bullard and Mitra (2002), Evans and Honkapohja (2003), and Orphanides and Williams (2005a)), recurrent hyperinflations in Latin America (Marcet and Nicolini (2003)), US inflation and disinflation (Sargent (1999), Orphanides and Williams (2005b), Bullard and Eusepi (2005)), asset prices (Timmermann (1993), Brock and Hommes (1998), Bullard and Duffy (2001), 3 Fama (1984) demonstrates that, for this to happen, the variance of the risk premium must be greater than the variance of expected depreciation, and their covariance must be negative.These requirements do not appear to be supported empirically.…”
Section: U S D /G B P U S D /D E M U Sd /Jay G B P /D E M G B P /Jaymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The LS dominance also has been challenged in previous applied studies (see Bullard and Eusepi, 2005;Carceles-Poveda and Giannitsarou, 2007). Hence, it remains open the question of which algorithm should be taken as representative from an empirical standpoint.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Learnability applications in the literature to date have been confined to very simple, small-scale models where these problems rarely come into play. 7 In the kind of medium-to large-scale models that policy institutions use, these issues cannot be safely ignored. 8 Without taking away anything from the important contributions of Bullard and 7 A notable exception is Garratt and Hall [22], but even then the learning problem was constrained to exchange rate determination.…”
Section: Expectational Equilibrium Under Adaptive Learningmentioning
confidence: 99%