2014
DOI: 10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2014.05.003
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Corruption in delegated public procurement auctions

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

1
20
0

Year Published

2014
2014
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
8
1

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 37 publications
(24 citation statements)
references
References 14 publications
1
20
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Given that public procurement accounts for on average 29% of total general government expenditure in OECD countries (2013 data) (OECD 2015), and closer to 50% of public spending in developing countries, these practices can cause serious damage to the economy and to public confidence in institutions. Favoritism in the allocation of public contracts can lead to higher prices, reduced value for money, the provision of low-quality or unsafe works, goods and services, and reduced competition (Bank 2016;Dastidar and Mukherjee 2014;Hessami 2014). It is also likely to harm democracy since, by distributing resources according to particularistic ties, partisan favoritism disadvantages parties that lack connections and thus weakens political competition (Stark and Vedres 2012).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Given that public procurement accounts for on average 29% of total general government expenditure in OECD countries (2013 data) (OECD 2015), and closer to 50% of public spending in developing countries, these practices can cause serious damage to the economy and to public confidence in institutions. Favoritism in the allocation of public contracts can lead to higher prices, reduced value for money, the provision of low-quality or unsafe works, goods and services, and reduced competition (Bank 2016;Dastidar and Mukherjee 2014;Hessami 2014). It is also likely to harm democracy since, by distributing resources according to particularistic ties, partisan favoritism disadvantages parties that lack connections and thus weakens political competition (Stark and Vedres 2012).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This practice is contrary to the public interest, because it does not guarantee that the best-performing company is awarded the contract. This is therefore likely to lead to inefficiency (Dal Bó & Rossi, 2007), lower service quality and extra service delivery costs (Dastidar & Mukherjee, 2014), which will ultimately be borne by users or by taxpayers (Rose-Ackerman, 1999;Tollison, 2012). In short, it adversely affects the expected social welfare of a contracting auction (Boehm & Olaya, 2006).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…20 Whenever the (DE) constraint does not bind and hence not restrict equilibrium effort, a higher δ has no impact on e A * . 21 Formally analyzing the problem of corruption in the contracting process with PMSCs could also yield very interesting results (for example building on Calzolari and Spagnolo, 2009;Dastidar and Mukherjee, 2014). However, we would have to extend the model and allow for agency problems within the government, which is beyond the scope of this paper.…”
Section: Multiple Agentsmentioning
confidence: 96%