2016
DOI: 10.1177/0956797616654455
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Cooperation, Fast and Slow

Abstract: Does cooperating require the inhibition of selfish urges? Or does "rational" self-interest constrain cooperative impulses? I investigated the role of intuition and deliberation in cooperation by meta-analyzing 67 studies in which cognitive-processing manipulations were applied to economic cooperation games (total N = 17,647; no indication of publication bias using Egger's test, Begg's test, or p-curve). My meta-analysis was guided by the social heuristics hypothesis, which proposes that intuition favors behavi… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

19
197
5

Year Published

2016
2016
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
8

Relationship

2
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 358 publications
(221 citation statements)
references
References 64 publications
(46 reference statements)
19
197
5
Order By: Relevance
“…Our key result, that people engage in less calculating behavior when their decision process is observable, provides the first evidence, to our knowledge, that people use uncalculating cooperation for reputational benefits, and not merely as a useful way to reduce the nonsocial costs of calculating (32)(33)(34)(35). Although a theory of uncalculating cooperation as merely an efficient decisionmaking strategy can explain our second and third results (individuals who cooperate across contexts to reduce the nonsocial costs of calculating will end up cooperating more, and thus should be perceived as, and should actually be, more trustworthy), it cannot explain why uncalculating decision-making should decrease when it is not observable.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 94%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…Our key result, that people engage in less calculating behavior when their decision process is observable, provides the first evidence, to our knowledge, that people use uncalculating cooperation for reputational benefits, and not merely as a useful way to reduce the nonsocial costs of calculating (32)(33)(34)(35). Although a theory of uncalculating cooperation as merely an efficient decisionmaking strategy can explain our second and third results (individuals who cooperate across contexts to reduce the nonsocial costs of calculating will end up cooperating more, and thus should be perceived as, and should actually be, more trustworthy), it cannot explain why uncalculating decision-making should decrease when it is not observable.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 94%
“…Likewise, our third result (that uncalculating cooperators really are more trustworthy) confirms that it can be beneficial to trust uncalculating cooperators: they really do return more money in the TG, suggesting that uncalculating cooperation serves as an honest signal of trustworthiness. This work builds on the finding that intuitive decisions are typically more cooperative (35) by showing that intuitive cooperation in one decision (compared with more calculated cooperation) predicts trustworthiness in a future decision.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…The SHH provides an adaptive logic for spillovers: because deliberation is often costly, it can be advantageous to rely on cognitively efficient but inflexible social heuristics, especially when one must make decisions quickly or one is distracted or fatigued (for a formal evolutionary game theoretic demonstration, see Bear and Rand (2016)). Empirical support for the SHH comes, for example, from the observation that experimentally inducing participants to decide more deliberatively (or less intuitively) leads to less cooperation – as shown in a meta-analysis of 51 pure cooperation studies where cognitive processing mode was experimentally manipulated using cognitive load, time constraints, ego depletion, or intuition inductions (Rand, 2016b). …”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…We used a broad definition of cognitive load (Rand, 2016), including an additional task, time pressure, ego depletion, stress, sleep deprivation, and a foreign language. Although obvious differences exist between the manipulations, they have all been theorized to tax the participant's executive functions.…”
Section: Cognitive-load Manipulationmentioning
confidence: 99%