2012
DOI: 10.1111/j.1574-0862.2012.00581.x
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Can economic incentives encourage actual reductions in pesticide use and environmental spillovers?

Abstract: Chemical pesticides constitute an important input in crop production. But their indiscriminate use can impact negatively agricultural productivity, human health, and the environment. Recently, attention is focused on the use of economic incentives to reduce pesticide use and its related indirect effects. The aim of this work is to assess the effectiveness of different economic instruments such as taxes and levies in encouraging farmers to decrease pesticide use and their environmental spillovers. A policy simu… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

1
48
0
9

Year Published

2013
2013
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
9

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 57 publications
(58 citation statements)
references
References 27 publications
1
48
0
9
Order By: Relevance
“…The efficiency of different incentive tools is discussed (e.g. pesticide taxation, quotas of pesticide use, subsidies) (Jacquet et al, 2011;Skevas et al, 2012). In other words, should farmers alone support the costs?…”
Section: Economics In the Process Of Changementioning
confidence: 99%
“…The efficiency of different incentive tools is discussed (e.g. pesticide taxation, quotas of pesticide use, subsidies) (Jacquet et al, 2011;Skevas et al, 2012). In other words, should farmers alone support the costs?…”
Section: Economics In the Process Of Changementioning
confidence: 99%
“…However, in order to reduce the reliance on pesticides significantly (and not making them dependent on less hazardous ones), a tax scheme has to go hand in hand with accompanying measures promoting preventive measures of integrated pest management. In the short-term, no environmental and human health benefits will be observed due to large hoarding activities by retailers and farmers (peaks in Figures 1-3), and low price elasticities [67,73]. So far, no clear indication could be found in the literature whether a tax is efficient or not: for example, Reus et al [11] find no notable or only a moderate effectiveness, whereas Oskam et al [5] and Falconer [12] notice a high/positive effectiveness.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The Netherlands, for example, have had several pesticide tax debates which led to the denial of a proposed taxation in the beginning of the millennium [3,64]. Arguments against a fiscal instrument were the relatively high organizational effort [65], the low elasticity of demand, and the higher burdens for domestic producers as well as leakage through import [3,66] (for the elasticity see also [67]). The aims proclaimed in the NAP until 2010 were reached at least partially: large parts of targets regarding environmental load and residue limits in water supply and food have been reached [68].…”
Section: Tax Discussion In Other European Countriesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The tax on these chemicals in itself does not reduce their use if it is not paired with the compensation of revenues (Falconer and Hodge, 2000). Skevasa et al (2012) confi rmed through the use of models that, in contrast to taxes on pesticides, the low toxicity pesticides, pesticide quotas and the support of environmentally friendly R&D results can reduce agrochemical use. From studies of French vineyards, Lescot et al (2011) have found that both environmental taxes and green subsidies can contribute to the returns on precision means.…”
Section: Methodology Estimation Of Savings In Pesticide Applicationsmentioning
confidence: 99%