2017
DOI: 10.1016/j.geb.2015.12.013
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Balance of power and the propensity of conflict

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1

Citation Types

0
3
0

Year Published

2019
2019
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 14 publications
(3 citation statements)
references
References 66 publications
0
3
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Although the economics and political science literature attempt to explain the roots and emergence of a conflict, they also adopt analytical tools, especially from game theory, to model interstate and intrastate conflicts. For instance, Skaperdas (1992); Powell (1993); Grossman and Kim (1995); Grossman and Mendoza (2001); Hirshleifer (2001); Muthoo (2004); McBride and Skaperdas (2014); and Herbst, Konrad and Morath (2017) [7,[32][33][34][35][36][37][38] ground their analysis of conflict in game theory models to explain their emergence and characterise their main features. All of the above contributions propose a similar solution, consisting of the definition of a set of parameters that drive players to opt for a peaceful settlement of their disputes.…”
Section: Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Although the economics and political science literature attempt to explain the roots and emergence of a conflict, they also adopt analytical tools, especially from game theory, to model interstate and intrastate conflicts. For instance, Skaperdas (1992); Powell (1993); Grossman and Kim (1995); Grossman and Mendoza (2001); Hirshleifer (2001); Muthoo (2004); McBride and Skaperdas (2014); and Herbst, Konrad and Morath (2017) [7,[32][33][34][35][36][37][38] ground their analysis of conflict in game theory models to explain their emergence and characterise their main features. All of the above contributions propose a similar solution, consisting of the definition of a set of parameters that drive players to opt for a peaceful settlement of their disputes.…”
Section: Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Moreover, these inequalities also affect future expectations in iterated exchange (Zeng et al, 2019). Therefore, when inter-hierarchical exchanges occur, the exercise of power alters the initial, hypothetical centrality of the game, with an eventual shift of the strategies of the players towards disjoint interests (Barker et al, 2015;Campennì and Schino, 2016;Cox et al, 2013;Herbst et al, 2017;Phillips, 2017;Wang et al, 2010) and, eventually, a decreased drive to engage into any deal.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Our study also relates to the experimental literature on bargaining in the shadow of conflict that examines, among other things, the effect of the asymmetry of conflict on bargaining outcomes (Hoffman and Spitzer, 1985; Kimbrough and Shremeta, 2014; Kimbrough et al ., 2014; Dechenaux et al ., 2015; Herbst et al ., 2017). Anbarci and Feltovich (2013) find that the negotiation strategies do not react to conflict asymmetries as much as the selfish sequentially rational theory would predict, but that QRE and other‐regarding preferences can account for the observed patterns.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%