2018
DOI: 10.1080/10361146.2018.1451487
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Australian bicameralism as semi-parliamentarism: patterns of majority formation in 29 democracies

Abstract: The article analyses the type of bicameralism we find in Australia as a distinct executive-legislative system -a hybrid between parliamentary and presidential government -which we call 'semiparliamentary government'. We argue that this hybrid presents an important and underappreciated alternative to pure parliamentary government as well as presidential forms of the power-separation, and that it can achieve a certain balance between competing models or visions of democracy. We specify theoretically how the semi… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
9
0
2

Year Published

2018
2018
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
4
2

Relationship

3
3

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 18 publications
(13 citation statements)
references
References 67 publications
0
9
0
2
Order By: Relevance
“…Since each cabinet party then becomes a veto player, and since more veto players may also reduce the value of agenda-setting powers, median outcomes are far from guaranteed (see also Martin and Vanberg 2014). This finding also implies that if governing with shifting, median-oriented legislative coalitions is seen as a normative priority, it might provide a reason to consider alternatives to a pure parliamentary system of government such as presidential or 'semi-parliamentary' government (see Ganghof 2018;Ganghof, Eppner, and Pörschke 2018).…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Since each cabinet party then becomes a veto player, and since more veto players may also reduce the value of agenda-setting powers, median outcomes are far from guaranteed (see also Martin and Vanberg 2014). This finding also implies that if governing with shifting, median-oriented legislative coalitions is seen as a normative priority, it might provide a reason to consider alternatives to a pure parliamentary system of government such as presidential or 'semi-parliamentary' government (see Ganghof 2018;Ganghof, Eppner, and Pörschke 2018).…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…However, this party cannot govern alone but has to seek issue-specific majority support in the more proportionally elected second chamber. Ganghof et al (2018) show that well-designed semi-parliamentary systems can achieve a position in the upper right quadrant of Figure 1. That is, they can achieve identifiable and stable one-party cabinets, governing with issue-specific multi-party coalitions in a multidimensional space.…”
Section: Semi-parliamentarism As Optimizationmentioning
confidence: 94%
“…While some goals of simple majoritarianism can be reconciled, to a certain de-gree, with some goals of complex majoritarianism, the underlying tension between the two models of democratic majority formation remains. Ganghof, Eppner, and Pörschke (2018) visualize this fact in a descriptive data analysis for the period from 1995-2015, which is partially reproduced in Figure 1. The two dimensions in the figure measure simple and complex majoritarianism respectively.…”
Section: An Empirical Visualizationmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Allerdings ist in unserer Konzeption ein Land wie Dänemark -anstatt der Schweiz -das polare Gegenmodell zum Westminster-System. Dieses Gegenmodell basiert nicht auf Konsens, sondern auch einer komplexeren Form der Mehrheitsfindung Ganghof et al 2018 Um nun die Zielkonflikte in den Fokus zu nehmen, aggregieren wir die jeweils drei Variablen der beiden konkurrierenden Konzeptionen zu getrennten Dimensionen (Abb. 2).…”
unclassified
“…3 deshalb positive Ausreißer: sie kombinieren hohe Werte bei den "majoritären" Zielen mit mittleren bis hohen Werten bei den "proportionalen" Zielen. Die anderen semiparlamentarischen System zeigen hingegen, dass eine semi-parlamentarische Verfassung eine besondere Zielbalance keineswegs garantiert (ausführlicher:Ganghof et al 2018).Natürlich hängt die Zielbalance auch von der institutionellen Macht der zweiten Kammern ab, was in der Abbildung nicht berücksichtigt werden kann (vgl.. In Victoria zum Beispiel begünstigt das institutionelle Design stark die Regierungsmehrheit in der ersten Kammer, u. a. durch die Möglichkeit beide Kammern aufzulösen und Konflikte in einer gemeinsamen Sitzung zu entscheiden.…”
unclassified