2009
DOI: 10.1007/s11166-009-9075-z
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Are risk preferences stable? Comparing an experimental measure with a validated survey-based measure

Abstract: We examine the stability of risk preference within subjects by comparing measures obtained from two elicitation methods, an economics experiment with real monetary rewards and a survey with questions on hypothetical gambles. The survey questions have been validated by numerous empirical studies of investment, insurance demand, smoking and alcohol use, and recent studies have shown the experimental measure is associated with several real-world risky behaviors. For the majority of subjects, we find that risk pre… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

3
104
4

Year Published

2011
2011
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
6
4

Relationship

0
10

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 171 publications
(111 citation statements)
references
References 38 publications
3
104
4
Order By: Relevance
“…Option B □ 0.9 probability of winning $3.85 and 0.1 probability of winning $0.10 10 Option A □ winning $2.00 with certainty Option B □ winning $3.85 with certainty 20 Our subjects seem to be slightly less risk-averse than subjects in other papers who used the Holt-Laury mechanism: for example, in Holt and Laury (2002) itself, 8% were risk-loving, 26% risk-neutral and 66% risk-averse, while in Anderson and Mellor (2009) and Lusk and Coble (2005) those numbers were 5%, 21% and 75%, and 12%, 24% and 64%, respectively. mean value of r for those with valid measures of r is 0.21, which is a slight degree of risk aversion.…”
Section: Appendix A: Measuring Risk Aversionmentioning
confidence: 61%
“…Option B □ 0.9 probability of winning $3.85 and 0.1 probability of winning $0.10 10 Option A □ winning $2.00 with certainty Option B □ winning $3.85 with certainty 20 Our subjects seem to be slightly less risk-averse than subjects in other papers who used the Holt-Laury mechanism: for example, in Holt and Laury (2002) itself, 8% were risk-loving, 26% risk-neutral and 66% risk-averse, while in Anderson and Mellor (2009) and Lusk and Coble (2005) those numbers were 5%, 21% and 75%, and 12%, 24% and 64%, respectively. mean value of r for those with valid measures of r is 0.21, which is a slight degree of risk aversion.…”
Section: Appendix A: Measuring Risk Aversionmentioning
confidence: 61%
“…However, there is no clear-cut evidence that real incentives generate different results than hypothetical incentives (Abdellaoui et al, 2011;Anderson and Mellor, 2009;Beattie and Loomes, 1997), only that they may reduce noise (Camerer and Hogarth, 1999).…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Both papers …nd evidence of rank stability across contexts involving stakes of the same or near orders of magnitude, while ours also …nds evidence of rank instability across contexts involving stakes of remote orders of magnitude. 3 Anderson and Mellor (2009) compare the responses of laboratory subjects to a series of hypothetical job gambles and a series of hypothetical inheritance gambles. The authors construct a categorical measure of the subjects' risk aversion based on the job gamble responses and then do the same for the inheritance gamble responses.…”
Section: Studies Using Market Datamentioning
confidence: 99%