2003
DOI: 10.1016/s0927-5371(03)00034-4
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

An experimental study on tournament design

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

2
115
2
3

Year Published

2004
2004
2020
2020

Publication Types

Select...
9

Relationship

2
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 170 publications
(122 citation statements)
references
References 27 publications
2
115
2
3
Order By: Relevance
“…However, when the noise is low (DET-L), subjects expend average effort of 62.4, which is lower than the equilibrium effort of 70.7 (two-tailed Wilcoxon test, p-value = 0.03). This is a surprising result, since previous studies find that efforts in deterministic winnertake-all contests (rank-order tournaments) are usually either higher or not significantly different from theoretical benchmarks (Bull et al, 1987;Harbring and Irlenbusch, 2003;Eriksson et al, 2009). The major difference of our study is the use of multiplicative noise to adjust individual final performance (Gerchak and He, 2003), whereas all other experimental studies employ additive noise (Lazear and Rosen, 1981).…”
Section: Overviewmentioning
confidence: 77%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…However, when the noise is low (DET-L), subjects expend average effort of 62.4, which is lower than the equilibrium effort of 70.7 (two-tailed Wilcoxon test, p-value = 0.03). This is a surprising result, since previous studies find that efforts in deterministic winnertake-all contests (rank-order tournaments) are usually either higher or not significantly different from theoretical benchmarks (Bull et al, 1987;Harbring and Irlenbusch, 2003;Eriksson et al, 2009). The major difference of our study is the use of multiplicative noise to adjust individual final performance (Gerchak and He, 2003), whereas all other experimental studies employ additive noise (Lazear and Rosen, 1981).…”
Section: Overviewmentioning
confidence: 77%
“…The most commonly used distribution in the experimental contest literature is uniform and the most commonly used cost function is quadratic (Bull et al, 1987;Harbring and Irlenbusch, 2003;Eriksson et al, 2009;Agranov and Tergiman, 2013). Therefore, we assume that and are i.i.d.…”
Section: The Theoretical Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…A second category of experimental work which is related to our study is constituted by experimental studies on tournament incentive schemes (see for example BULL, SCHOTTER, and WEIGELT 1987, VAN DIJK, SONNEMANS, and VAN WINDEN 2001, HARBRING and IRLENBUSCH 2003, ORRISON, SCHOTTER, and WEIGELT 2004, HARBRING and IRLENBUSCH 5 ISAAC, WALKER, and THOMAS (1984 invite experienced participants back to the laboratory and find that behaviour of experienced and inexperienced subjects is basically the same. A similar restart effect is observed by CROSON (1996).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In fixed prize tournaments contestants can engage in collusive behavior by jointly reducing their effort, or in sabotage by taking actions to reduce each other's performance, knowing that the full prize will be paid out anyway (Harbring and Irlenbusch, 2003;Bandiera et al, 2005;Harbring et al, 2007). If the size of the prize (positively) depends on the agents' joint output, both collusion and sabotage are less attractive, because they lead to a smaller prize.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%