2019
DOI: 10.1016/j.red.2019.02.003
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Aggregate productivity and the allocation of resources over the business cycle

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

1
18
0

Year Published

2019
2019
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
8

Relationship

2
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 23 publications
(19 citation statements)
references
References 38 publications
1
18
0
Order By: Relevance
“…To measure the misallocation degree of resources, that is, labor and capital among regions, first, we need to measure the output elasticity of labor and capital. This paper refers to the practice of Osotimehin [50], using the Solow residual value to measure the elasticity. Suppose the production function is a C-D production function with the same scale return, i.e.,…”
Section: Calculating the Output Elasticity Of Resourcementioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…To measure the misallocation degree of resources, that is, labor and capital among regions, first, we need to measure the output elasticity of labor and capital. This paper refers to the practice of Osotimehin [50], using the Solow residual value to measure the elasticity. Suppose the production function is a C-D production function with the same scale return, i.e.,…”
Section: Calculating the Output Elasticity Of Resourcementioning
confidence: 99%
“…where CC represents carbon emissions of cement consumption; Q denotes total cement production; β denotes the carbon emissions coefficients, refer to Zhang H [50,55], the value is 0.5270tCO 2 /t. Hence, the formula for calculating the total amount of CO 2 emissions in each region is CO 2 = EC + CC.…”
Section: Calculating the Carbon Intensitymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In focusing on the consequences of barriers to labor reallocation on aggregate productivity growth, our analysis goes one step beyond the recent literature on misallocation that focuses on the level effects, following the seminal work of Restuccia and Rogerson (2008) and Hsieh and Klenow (2009). Empirical studies that evaluate the contribution of reallocation to productivity changes, such as Foster et al (2001) and Osotimehin (2016), are designed to analyze the sources of productivity growth, rather than the level; in that sense, our analysis is more comparable to that literature. We highlight that barriers to reallocation affect not only the allocation of resources across firms with different productivity levels, but also the productivity process itself as it modifies the firms' incentives to innovate.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The study by Fontagné & Santoni (2015) takes a similar position, showing that misallocation applies particularly to small and old firms. Osotimehin (2016) considers, on the one hand, the significance of reallocation towards the most productive continuing firms and, on the other, the process of creative destruction. The author shows that, over the period 1989-2007, the contribution of reallocation towards the most productive continuing firms to the evolution of French sectoral total factor productivity (TFP) is greater than that resulting from a Schumpeterian process of creative destruction.…”
Section: Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The decomposition of the average annual growth rate of sectoral TFP does not take into account reallocations between sectors. Osotimehin (2016) shows that cross-sectoral reallocations play a limited role in aggregate productivity trends.…”
Section: * * *mentioning
confidence: 99%