2016
DOI: 10.1098/rstb.2015.0099
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

A simple rule for the evolution of contingent cooperation in large groups

Abstract: One contribution of 18 to a theme issue 'The evolution of cooperation based on direct fitness benefits'. Humans cooperate in large groups of unrelated individuals, and many authors have argued that such cooperation is sustained by contingent reward and punishment. However, such sanctioning systems can also stabilize a wide range of behaviours, including mutually deleterious behaviours. Moreover, it is very likely that large-scale cooperation is derived in the human lineage. Thus, understanding the evolution of… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
11
0

Year Published

2016
2016
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
6
2
1

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 18 publications
(11 citation statements)
references
References 25 publications
(80 reference statements)
0
11
0
Order By: Relevance
“…There are additional reasons why reciprocity should occur particularly often between relatives (cf. [199]). Closely related individuals interact particularly frequently with each other owing to spatial viscosity [200,201], and groups of relatives are often small (e.g.…”
Section: Which Conditions Select For Reciprocity?mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…There are additional reasons why reciprocity should occur particularly often between relatives (cf. [199]). Closely related individuals interact particularly frequently with each other owing to spatial viscosity [200,201], and groups of relatives are often small (e.g.…”
Section: Which Conditions Select For Reciprocity?mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In our model, the maintenance of pro-social punishment relies on a small minority which supports them, but their robustness stems from the fact that they are constantly challenged by the presence of players that stop cooperating in the absence of pro-social institutions. This combination is empirically prevalent, with resilient public goods often being supported by a minority of contributors [51]. The key to the maintenance of the public good is the observability of institutions: only public knowledge of the presence of punishment institutions allows the conditional strategies that ultimately prevent the rise of anti-social behaviour, either in the form of defection or in the form of coordinated anti-social punishment institutions that never rise to high abundance, but can undermine the public good.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…(Online version in colour.) empirically prevalent, with resilient public goods often being supported by a minority of contributors [51]. The key to the maintenance of the public good is the observability of institutions: only public knowledge of the presence of punishment institutions allows the conditional strategies that ultimately prevent the rise of anti-social behaviour, either in the form of defection or in the form of coordinated anti-social punishment institutions that never rise to high abundance, but can undermine the public good.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The norm of reciprocity is considered a relatively universal disposition (Gouldner, 1960) and a fundamental organizing process in group formation and maintenance (Fehr, Fischbacher, & Gächter, 2002;Schonmann & Boyd, 2016). Reciprocity is a fundamentally communicative act, motivated through social comparison and aspirational homophily processes (Whitaker, Colombo, Allen, & Dunbar, 2016), and thus, communicative behavior is generally reciprocal in structure and content (Friedman & Singh, 2004), and such links tend to be more stable than nonreciprocated links (Rogers & Kincaid, 1981).…”
Section: Bit For Bit Byte For Byte: Reciprocity At Scalementioning
confidence: 99%