2012
DOI: 10.1093/qje/qjs009
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

A General Equilibrium Model of Sovereign Default and Business Cycles

Abstract: for helpful comments and suggestions. We also acknowledge comments by participants at various seminars and conferences. † This version of the paper was prepared while Enrique Mendoza was a visiting scholar with the Research Department, and he is grateful for Department's hospitality and support. Emerging markets business cycle models treat default risk as part of an exogenous interest rate on working capital, while sovereign default models treat income fluctuations as an exogenous endowment process with ad-noc… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
2

Citation Types

21
353
1
6

Year Published

2013
2013
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 438 publications
(385 citation statements)
references
References 45 publications
21
353
1
6
Order By: Relevance
“…In particular, a related work is by Mendoza and Yue (2012) who are the first to endogenize the cost of default: a sovereign default forces the private sector to use less efficient resources. We propose an alternative and complementary source for output costs: a disruption in domestic lending triggered by nonperforming sovereign bonds in domestic banks' balance sheets.…”
Section: Related Literaturementioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…In particular, a related work is by Mendoza and Yue (2012) who are the first to endogenize the cost of default: a sovereign default forces the private sector to use less efficient resources. We propose an alternative and complementary source for output costs: a disruption in domestic lending triggered by nonperforming sovereign bonds in domestic banks' balance sheets.…”
Section: Related Literaturementioning
confidence: 99%
“…Argentina's output dynamics before and after the default event mostly lie within the 99% confidence bands of the model simulations. As in Mendoza and Yue (2012), the v-shaped recovery of output after a default event is driven by two forces: TFP and re-access to credit. TFP is mean-reverting and thus very likely to recover after defaults.…”
mentioning
confidence: 93%
“…Guerrón-Quintana and Jinnai (2014) use a similar framework to study the effect of the 2008-09 liquidity crash on U.S. economic growth. Gornemann (2014) combines the endogenous default model of Mendoza and Yue (2012) with the variety model of Romer (1990) to study how endogenous growth affects the decision of the sovereign to default. Because default increases the price of imported intermediate goods in his model, it decreases the expected profits of potential entrants and, hence, depresses productivity growth.…”
Section: Related Literaturementioning
confidence: 99%
“…Figure 13 During that period, the average debt-to-GDP ratio for developed economies is about 10 percentage points higher than that in emerging economies. 30 How do the differences in precision levels affect debt and default dynamics in our model? The left panels of Figure plot the debt level as a function of the news precision and corresponding Theill's Us in the upper and lower panels, respectively.…”
Section: News Precision and Hump-shaped Default Patternmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…29 Notice that on the right panel of Figure 6 the country with Theill's U coefficient 0.8 (Peru) appears as an outlier. 30 Reinhart, Rogoff and Savastano (2003) The upper left panel shows the default rates by income decile that we estimate using data for 118 countries covering 1950-2003. The upper right and lower panels plot the number of defaults and the associated opacity or Theill's U measures.…”
Section: News Precision and Hump-shaped Default Patternmentioning
confidence: 99%