2018
DOI: 10.1016/j.jmoneco.2018.07.004
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Sovereign defaults and banking crises

Abstract: Episodes of sovereign default feature three key empirical regularities in connection with the banking systems of the countries where they occur: (i) sovereign defaults and banking crises tend to happen together, (ii) commercial banks have substantial holdings of government debt, and (iii) sovereign defaults result in major contractions in bank credit and production. This paper provides a rationale for these phenomena by extending the traditional sovereign default framework to incorporate bankers who lend to bo… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1

Citation Types

2
39
0

Year Published

2018
2018
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
8
1

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 89 publications
(41 citation statements)
references
References 43 publications
(40 reference statements)
2
39
0
Order By: Relevance
“…There are strong theoretical and empirical reasons to expect causal links between sovereign default and the fragility of the banking system. For instance, Sosa-Padilla (2015) argues that the main costs of sovereign default arise from the impact on the balance sheets of banks holding that debt, as they sharply contract corporate lending leading, while Brunnermeier et al (2016) suggest that there may be a "diabolic loop" linking soveriegn and bank credit risk. Such links can motivate why the central bank chooses to accommodate sovereign risk.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…There are strong theoretical and empirical reasons to expect causal links between sovereign default and the fragility of the banking system. For instance, Sosa-Padilla (2015) argues that the main costs of sovereign default arise from the impact on the balance sheets of banks holding that debt, as they sharply contract corporate lending leading, while Brunnermeier et al (2016) suggest that there may be a "diabolic loop" linking soveriegn and bank credit risk. Such links can motivate why the central bank chooses to accommodate sovereign risk.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The key difference relative to our setup is that these studies assume a representative agent and do not focus on default on domestic debt-holders. Other studies in this literature related to our work include those focusing on the effects of default on domestic agents, foreign and domestic lenders, optimal taxation, the role of secondary markets, discriminatory versus nondiscriminatory default and bailouts (e.g., Guembel and Sussman [30]; Broner et al [15]; Gennaioli et al [29]; Aguiar and Amador [1]; Mengus [42]; Di Casola and Sichlimiris [23]; Perez [46]; Bocola [14]; Sosa-Padilla [50]; and Paczos and Shakhnov [44]). As in some of these studies, default in our setup is nondiscriminatory, but in general, these studies abstract from distributional default incentives and social benefits of debt for self-insurance, liquidity and risk-sharing.…”
Section: Figure 1: Eurozone Debt Ratios and Spreadsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Strategic default on domestic government debt has recently been studied by D’Erasmo and Mendoza (), Juessen and Schabert (), Sosa‐Padilla () and Pouzo (). However, different from our article, D’Erasmo and Mendoza () focus on redistributive implications.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Juessen and Schabert () consider a setup with risk‐neutral agents and exogenous default costs. Similar to our approach, Sosa‐Padilla () invokes a working capital constraint to generate endogenous default costs but the government's default decision is binary and debt is again priced by risk‐neutral agents. Pouzo () proceeds under the assumption that the government can commit to its tax policy but not to the repayment of outstanding debt; different from our model, default triggers a temporary breakdown of the primary bond market but debt continues to be traded on secondary markets and hence retains a positive valuation in anticipation of a future recovery of the primary market.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%