1998
DOI: 10.1093/oep/50.4.607
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Who should be on workfare? the use of work requirements as part of an optimal tax mix

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

0
45
0
1

Year Published

2005
2005
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
6
1

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 41 publications
(46 citation statements)
references
References 8 publications
0
45
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…equation (5) subject to the individual labour supply of workers (1), the constraints (2)-(4), the minimum utility requirement of non-workers (6), and the requirement that all variables are non-negative. In this way, we obtain all the Pareto optimal benefit policies parameterized on b.…”
Section: Optimal Benefit Policiesmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 3 more Smart Citations
“…equation (5) subject to the individual labour supply of workers (1), the constraints (2)-(4), the minimum utility requirement of non-workers (6), and the requirement that all variables are non-negative. In this way, we obtain all the Pareto optimal benefit policies parameterized on b.…”
Section: Optimal Benefit Policiesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…(7) may be in conflict with the labor market participation constraint in (2) and with the minimum transfer level in (6). Note, that the labour market participation constraint implies that the benefit level has to be below some upper boundb.…”
Section: Pecuniary Benefit Systemsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…5 See also Besley and Coate (1995), Brett (1998), Cuff (2000, and Kanbur, Keen and Tuomola (1994). 6 See also Diamond (1980) who first addressed the extensive margin in a Mirrlees' type model.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%