2013
DOI: 10.1007/s00182-013-0370-1
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

When is tit-for-tat unbeatable?

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
21
0

Year Published

2015
2015
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

1
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 29 publications
(24 citation statements)
references
References 24 publications
0
21
0
Order By: Relevance
“…This implies that conformity can help to avoid inequality between the two players [ 44 45 ]. In particular, when one of p 1 and p 2 equals to 1, | E ( S 1 )− E ( S 2 )| must be less than T − S , which is the maximal payoff difference between outcomes in the one-shot PD game [ 10 , 11 ]. However, when p 1 + p 2 = 0, the payoff difference between the two players is linearly increasing in , where the player with higher initial cooperative level is exploited by the other.…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This implies that conformity can help to avoid inequality between the two players [ 44 45 ]. In particular, when one of p 1 and p 2 equals to 1, | E ( S 1 )− E ( S 2 )| must be less than T − S , which is the maximal payoff difference between outcomes in the one-shot PD game [ 10 , 11 ]. However, when p 1 + p 2 = 0, the payoff difference between the two players is linearly increasing in , where the player with higher initial cooperative level is exploited by the other.…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For instance in Axelrod's tournament, the dominating strategy (Tit-fortat) was not the most complex of all the proposed strategies (Axelrod, 1980). Further, research in economics also indicate that repeated games and social interactions do not always select for more complex strategies, and these results were obtained either by taking into account explicitly the costs of cognitive complexity (Binmore & Samuelson, 1992) or, more recently, in the absence of such costs (Duersch, Oechssler, & Schipper, 2014;Horv ath, Kov a rík, & Mengel, 2012;Mohlin, 2012). All this suggests that it is relevant to try to characterize the type of games species are playing in nature (or the social problems they face), in order to characterize the real demands on social cognition.…”
Section: Evolutionary Paths To Increased Cognitionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For instance, Duersch, Oechssler, and Schipper (2012) characterize the class of symmetric two-player games in which imitate-if-better cannot be beaten by any other decision rule no matter how sophisticated. Similarly, Duersch, Oechssler, and Schipper (2014) show that in symmetric two-player game tit-for-tat cannot be beaten by any other decision rule if and only if the game is an exact potential game. Another paper related to our work is Ellison (1997), who analyzes a large population which besides of players following a version of fictitious play also contains a single rational player.…”
mentioning
confidence: 87%
“…Their focus is on estimating such learning models with experimental data. There are only a few theoretical papers on learning in games in which players follow different learning theories (Banerjee and Weibull, 1995 Schipper, 2012Schipper, , 2014. They focus on the evolutionary selection or relative success of different boundedly rational learning rules.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%