1980
DOI: 10.1007/bf02299869
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Welfare effects of price discrimination when demand curves are constant elasticity

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
4
1

Citation Types

0
15
0

Year Published

1985
1985
2016
2016

Publication Types

Select...
4
2

Relationship

0
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 11 publications
(15 citation statements)
references
References 12 publications
0
15
0
Order By: Relevance
“…See Aguirre, Cowan and Vickers (2010) for sufficient conditions based on the shape of the demand and inverse demand functions to determine the sign of the welfare effect. 8 Ippolito (1980) and more recently Cowan (2011) analyze the effect of third-degree price discrimination on consumer surplus and find reasonable settings where the effect is positive. In a related paper Leeson and Sobel (2008) consider costly price discrimination.…”
Section: Welfare Effectsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…See Aguirre, Cowan and Vickers (2010) for sufficient conditions based on the shape of the demand and inverse demand functions to determine the sign of the welfare effect. 8 Ippolito (1980) and more recently Cowan (2011) analyze the effect of third-degree price discrimination on consumer surplus and find reasonable settings where the effect is positive. In a related paper Leeson and Sobel (2008) consider costly price discrimination.…”
Section: Welfare Effectsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Schmalensee (1981)'s direct approach to the welfare effect and Varian's celebrated bounds on social welfare (1985,1989,1992) have dominated both the research and the teaching of the welfare effects of third-degree price discrimination for the last twenty-five years. Our analysis, inspired by the pioneering work by Ippolito (1980) and its generalization to n markets by Aguirre (2008), offers some advantages over Schmalensee's and Varian's. Firstly, it focuses directly on the change in welfare (instead of on indirect Lagrangian techniques or on exogenous bounds) and allows the output effect (that is, the social valuation of the change in total output) to be distinguished neatly from the misallocation effect.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Greenhut and Ohta (1976) show through a numerical example that price discrimination may increase output with constant elasticity demands. Ippolito (1980) obtains the result via numerical simulations that total output increases under third-degree price discrimination in the two-market case. Formby, Layson and Smith (1983) using Lagrangean techniques show that monopolistic price discrimination increases total output over a wide range of constant elasticities.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 93%
“…Since third-degree price discrimination is viewed as an ine¢ cient way of distributing a given quantity of output between di¤erent consumers or submarkets, an increase in total output is a necessary condition for price discrimination to increase social welfare (Robinson, 1933, Ippolito, 1980, Schmalensee, 1981, Varian, 1985, Schwartz, 1990, and Bertoletti, 2004. So a focal point in the literature has been the analysis of the e¤ects of price discrimination on output: in the case of linear demand price discrimination does not change output when all markets are served (Pigou, 1920, andRobinson, 1933), but in the general non-linear case the e¤ect of price discrimination on output and, therefore, on welfare may be either positive or negative.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation