1997
DOI: 10.1016/s0165-1765(97)00190-0
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Welfare effects of discriminatory two-parts tariffs constrained by price caps

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

0
5
0

Year Published

2002
2002
2015
2015

Publication Types

Select...
9

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 13 publications
(5 citation statements)
references
References 4 publications
0
5
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Compared to tariff-basket regulation, this confers the firm greater flexibility in tariff rebalancing but lack of convergence to a welfare-maximizing equilibrium. 6 The literature proves that, under non-stochastic (or stable) conditions of costs and demand and myopic profit maximization (that is, when the firm does not take into account future periods in its current profit maximizing behavior), the use of the chained Laspeyres index makes the prices of the regulated firm intertemporally converge to Ramsey-Boiteaux pricing (Vogelsang, 2001, Vogelsang, 1989, Bertoletti and Poletti, 1997, Loeb and Magat, 1979, and Sibley, 1989. The chained Laspeyres structure simultaneously reconciles two opposing objectives: the maximization of social welfare and the individual rationality of the firm (i.e., non-negative profits).…”
Section: Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Compared to tariff-basket regulation, this confers the firm greater flexibility in tariff rebalancing but lack of convergence to a welfare-maximizing equilibrium. 6 The literature proves that, under non-stochastic (or stable) conditions of costs and demand and myopic profit maximization (that is, when the firm does not take into account future periods in its current profit maximizing behavior), the use of the chained Laspeyres index makes the prices of the regulated firm intertemporally converge to Ramsey-Boiteaux pricing (Vogelsang, 2001, Vogelsang, 1989, Bertoletti and Poletti, 1997, Loeb and Magat, 1979, and Sibley, 1989. The chained Laspeyres structure simultaneously reconciles two opposing objectives: the maximization of social welfare and the individual rationality of the firm (i.e., non-negative profits).…”
Section: Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Average-revenue regulation allows for greater flexibility in the Transco's tariff rebalancing strategy, but then lacks a method to converge to the welfare maximizing equilibrium. The literature has demonstrated that with a myopic (short-term oriented) profit maximization outlook and under stable (non-stochastic) cost and demand conditions, a chained Laspeyres index will cause firm prices to converge intertemporally to the Ramsey-Boiteaux pricing (Vogelsang 2001;Vogelsang 1989;Bertoletti and Poletti 1997;Loeb and Magat 1979;and Sibley 1989). This is accomplished by simultaneously reconciling between social welfare maximization and the individual rationality of the regulated firm.…”
Section: Related Literaturementioning
confidence: 99%
“…Compared to tariff-basket regulation, this confers the firm greater flexibility in tariff rebalancing but lack of convergence to the welfare maximizing equilibrium. The literature has proved that, under non-stochastic (or stable) conditions of costs and demand and myopic profit maximization (that is, when the firm does not take into account future periods in its current profit maximizing behavior), the use of the chained Laspeyres index makes the prices of the regulated firm intertemporally converge to Ramsey-Boiteaux pricing (Vogelsang, 2001, Vogelsang, 1989, Bertoletti and Poletti, 1997, Loeb and Magat 1979, and Sibley, 1989. The chained-Laspeyres structure simultaneously reconciles two opposing objectives: the maximization of social welfare and the individual rationality of the firm (i.e., non-negative profits).…”
Section: Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%