2011
DOI: 10.1007/s11166-011-9129-x
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Viewing the future through a warped lens: Why uncertainty generates hyperbolic discounting

Abstract: A large body of experimental research has demonstrated that, on average, people violate the axioms of expected utility theory as well as of discounted utility theory. In particular, aggregate behavior is best characterized by probability distortions and hyperbolic discounting. But is it the same people who are prone to these behaviors? Based on an experiment with salient monetary incentives we demonstrate that there is a strong and significant relationship between greater departures from linear probability wei… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1

Citation Types

2
68
0

Year Published

2012
2012
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
6
3

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 146 publications
(70 citation statements)
references
References 60 publications
2
68
0
Order By: Relevance
“…and w(. ), we use a simple and easy to understand procedure introduced in Fehr-Duda et al (2006) and successfully employed to estimate utility function and probability weighting function parameters in several subsequent studies (including: Bruhin et al 2010;Fehr-Duda et al 2010;and Epper et al 2011). Because it uses a choice list elicitation task which is very similar in structure to our incentivised confidence elicitation task, it is particularly well suited to our study as its use minimises the cognitive load involved in subjects learning how to respond to the two types of task.…”
Section: Methodsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…and w(. ), we use a simple and easy to understand procedure introduced in Fehr-Duda et al (2006) and successfully employed to estimate utility function and probability weighting function parameters in several subsequent studies (including: Bruhin et al 2010;Fehr-Duda et al 2010;and Epper et al 2011). Because it uses a choice list elicitation task which is very similar in structure to our incentivised confidence elicitation task, it is particularly well suited to our study as its use minimises the cognitive load involved in subjects learning how to respond to the two types of task.…”
Section: Methodsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Heteroskedasticity in the error variance across elicitation tables is accounted for, as in Epper et al (2011), by assuming the standard deviation of the distribution of the error term, v L , is proportional to the difference between the guaranteed amounts in Option B as one moves down the rows of the table. Hence, v L = v(x 1L − x 2L ), where v denotes an additional parameter to be estimated.…”
Section: Methodsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The connection seems to arise because, in contrast to sure consequences in the near future, delayed consequences are perceived as inherently risky (Dasgupta and Maskin, 2005). As such, non-linear probability transformations like those which some writers such as Kahneman and Tversky (1979) and Tversky and Kahneman (1992) applied to explain Allais-like behavior can also adjust discount factors in order to help explain choice of timed outcomes (Epper et al, 2011;Baucells and Heukamp, 2012).…”
Section: Timing and Nonlinear Expectationsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Remark 4 There exists an interesting discussion in the theoretical and experimental literature about whether hyperbolic time discounting is conceptually nothing else than rank dependent decision making under an uncertain stopping time as, e.g., represented by mortality risks (cf., e.g., Halevy (2008) and Epper et al (2011) as well as references therein). Although QHD life-cycle models can, by (18) and (21), be formally subsumed under our RDU life-cycle model, we do not claim that hyperbolic time discounting reduces in general to rank dependent decision making.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%