2011
DOI: 10.1016/j.jedc.2010.10.009
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Understanding liquidity shortages during severe economic downturns

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

1
15
0

Year Published

2014
2014
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
4
1

Relationship

3
2

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 6 publications
(16 citation statements)
references
References 21 publications
(13 reference statements)
1
15
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Following Tirole (), we will rewrite the ICC more compactly as pH1stitrueRît+1Asti,where A=pHBΔp denotes the entrepreneur's agency rent and the right‐hand side of equation is the minimum payment to the entrepreneur that would preserve his incentive to not shirk. The fact that the minimum incentive compatible payment is a function of sti is consistent with the standard assumption that an individual's propensity to shirk is decreasing in their stake in the project (see Holmstrom and Tirole , , Tirole , Atolia, Einarson, and Marquis , and Atolia, Gibson, and Marquis ).…”
Section: The Modelsupporting
confidence: 74%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Following Tirole (), we will rewrite the ICC more compactly as pH1stitrueRît+1Asti,where A=pHBΔp denotes the entrepreneur's agency rent and the right‐hand side of equation is the minimum payment to the entrepreneur that would preserve his incentive to not shirk. The fact that the minimum incentive compatible payment is a function of sti is consistent with the standard assumption that an individual's propensity to shirk is decreasing in their stake in the project (see Holmstrom and Tirole , , Tirole , Atolia, Einarson, and Marquis , and Atolia, Gibson, and Marquis ).…”
Section: The Modelsupporting
confidence: 74%
“…They enter the model through firm‐level moral hazard that exists between the entrepreneurs and their investors due to the entrepreneurs' ability to alter their funded project's probability of success through their choice of effort (high/low). This approach to modeling financial frictions is described in Holmstrom and Tirole (, ), Tirole (), and Atolia, Einarsson, and Marquis () and is shown by Atolia, Gibson, and Marquis () to produce realistically asymmetric business cycles within a calibrated DSGE model. As in Atolia, Gibson, and Marquis (), investors finance two‐period projects in an equity market, where the funding is used by the entrepreneurs to rent capital and pay workers.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…During the first period, time t, capital and labor must be acquired for use in the project. The inclusion of capital as a factor of production represents a departure from the model presented in Atolia et al (2011), who abstract from capital accumulation. As we show later, the addition of capital allows the current model to match the standard business cycle facts more closely and makes further quantitative exercises possible.…”
Section: Household Sector: the Entrepreneurs' Problemsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…As project size is increasing in s i t , its presence in this term captures the fact that the entrepreneur's private benefit from shirking increases as the project becomes larger. [See Atolia et al (2011) for more details on this point. ]…”
Section: Household Sector: the Entrepreneurs' Problemsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The first deals with the importance of liquidity constraints in financing. Liquidity shortages are characterized by Holmstrom and Tirole (), hereafter HT, and Atolia, Einarsson and Marquis (), hereafter AEM, as arising from the limited pledgeable income associated with funded projects in the presence of moral hazard. Adverse shocks to firms may result in termination of ongoing projects, which in aggregate could reduce overall economic activity if the provision of private liquidity is curtailed.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%