2019
DOI: 10.1596/1813-9450-8825
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Trading off the Income Gains and the Inequality Costs of Trade Policy

Abstract: This paper characterizes the trade-off between the income gains and the inequality costs of trade using survey data for 54 developing countries. Tariff data on agricultural and manufacturing goods are combined with household survey data on detailed income and expenditure patterns to estimate the first order effects of the elimination of tariffs on household welfare. We assess how these welfare effects vary across the distribution by estimating impacts on the consumption of traded goods, wage income, farm and n… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

2
11
0

Year Published

2020
2020
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
6
2

Relationship

2
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 13 publications
(13 citation statements)
references
References 48 publications
2
11
0
Order By: Relevance
“…In other words, while acknowledging a substantial degree of heterogeneity across trade agreements, our findings point towards a positive and economically significant effect - 2013; Artuc and McLaren, 2015;Lin and Fu, 2016), and that deriving higher growth rates may go hand in hand with higher wage inequality (Grossman and Helpman, 2018;Artuc et al, 2019). Other authors argue that side effects may feed in into politics (Autor et al, 2016;Colantone and Stanig, 2018a;Colantone and Stanig, 2018b), and studies on some potential policy responses are becoming available (i.a., see Claeys and Sapir, 2018, on the European Globalization Adjustment Fund).…”
Section: Discussionsupporting
confidence: 50%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…In other words, while acknowledging a substantial degree of heterogeneity across trade agreements, our findings point towards a positive and economically significant effect - 2013; Artuc and McLaren, 2015;Lin and Fu, 2016), and that deriving higher growth rates may go hand in hand with higher wage inequality (Grossman and Helpman, 2018;Artuc et al, 2019). Other authors argue that side effects may feed in into politics (Autor et al, 2016;Colantone and Stanig, 2018a;Colantone and Stanig, 2018b), and studies on some potential policy responses are becoming available (i.a., see Claeys and Sapir, 2018, on the European Globalization Adjustment Fund).…”
Section: Discussionsupporting
confidence: 50%
“…Therefore, using the coefficient estimated in equation 3, we construct five different scenarios where we assume a reduction in bilateral trade costs for a varying set of Latin we perform the estimations with aggregate bilateral data. This means that we do not account for possible heterogeneous effects across the distribution of sectors, firms and households (Grossman and Helpman, 2018;Artuc et al, 2019). Finally, we recall that trade in services, inherently different from trade in goods (see Mattoo et al, 2006), and the effects of its liberalization are outside the scope of this paper.…”
Section: General Equilibrium Theory Scenarios and Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…However, the results do not consider the dynamic gains associated with reduced tariffs, and therefore increased trade integration through a greater scope for technological progress, as discussed in the literature, and summarized in Table 7 of this report. Artuc, Porto and Rijkers (2017).…”
Section: What Do the Results Show For Nepal?mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Source: World Bank (2016) 33_Using data from the Ministry of Finance, Wagle (2011) shows that VAT revenue coming from imports exceeded 60 percent in the 10 years before this study. In a recent contribution, Artuc, Porto and Rijkers (2017), look at income gains and inequality costs of trade reforms using survey data for 54 developing countries including Nepal. They combine tariffs on agricultural and manufacturing goods with household survey data on income and expenditure patterns, and estimate the first order effects of the elimination of tariffs on household welfare.…”
Section: Improving the Import-to-export Environment Through Tradementioning
confidence: 99%
“…156 The consumption gains resulting from lower prices tend to be widely distributed (as most people consume many different products), but job losses in import-competing sectors tend to be highly concentrated (as most people usually only have one job -which if lost to import competition is a major shock). 157  Lower prices due to trade liberalization are often not fully passed on to consumers. Evidence from Ethiopia and Nigeria suggests that intermediaries capture most of the surplus from lowering international trade barriers.…”
Section: Digital Transactions Help People Build Savingsmentioning
confidence: 99%