1992
DOI: 10.1016/0010-0285(92)90015-t
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Thinking through uncertainty: Nonconsequential reasoning and choice

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

20
415
4
8

Year Published

2000
2000
2015
2015

Publication Types

Select...
4
4

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 548 publications
(452 citation statements)
references
References 32 publications
20
415
4
8
Order By: Relevance
“…First, the overall level of disjunction effect was much lower than that observed by Shafir and Tversky (1992). However, our results are consistent with other recent similar research (Matthew & Busemeyer, 2010; see also Croson, 1999, for a demonstration of a weaker disjunction effect with an 'imagining' procedure similar to the one we adopted).…”
Section: -------------------------Table 1----------------------------supporting
confidence: 92%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…First, the overall level of disjunction effect was much lower than that observed by Shafir and Tversky (1992). However, our results are consistent with other recent similar research (Matthew & Busemeyer, 2010; see also Croson, 1999, for a demonstration of a weaker disjunction effect with an 'imagining' procedure similar to the one we adopted).…”
Section: -------------------------Table 1----------------------------supporting
confidence: 92%
“…Second, we did not observe a disjunction effect in the way Shafir and Tversky (1992) did. We found that, when the optimal strategy was D, in the standard Prisoner's Dilemma game, Pr(D|Known D)>Pr(D|Known C), Pr(D| Unknown).…”
Section: Discussioncontrasting
confidence: 59%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Table 4 shows that 61% (48/79) of B signals led to [A,A] outcomes, compared to the 55% (197/360) probability of an [A,A] outcome in the NS treatment. This result may be analogous to the nonconsequentalist reasoning discussed by Shafir and Tversky (1992) and Croson (1999), where (in a prisoner's dilemma) a player is more likely to cooperate when he does not know the action of the other player than when he knows the other player has chosen the cooperative move. 24 Note that B signals were made only 81% of the time in their Aumann's conjecture test; moreover, in a third Clark et al game where players have a clear incentive to report truthfully, the chance of a B signal is only 51.5% and the likelihood of B play is only about 29.5% (this figure provided by Martin Sefton).…”
Section: Resultssupporting
confidence: 63%
“…One phenomenon is called nonconsequentalist reasoning and demonstrates a violation of the Savage (1954) sure-thing principle, as people "often do not consider appropriately each of the relevant branches of a decision tree." 11 Timing of decisions may also have an effect: Newcomb's problem (Nozick, 1969) shows the delicate 10 See Shafir and Tversky, 1992, and Croson, 1997. Note that payoffs in these experiments reflected choices actually made by subjects.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%