2015
DOI: 10.1111/ajps.12223
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The Voters' Curses: Why We Need Goldilocks Voters

Abstract: Scholars have long deplored voters' lack of interest in politics and argued in favor of greater political engagement. We present a formal theory of elections where successful communication of campaign messages requires both effort by candidates and attention from voters. Voters' interest in politics affects their attention and impacts the effectiveness of the electoral process as a screening and disciplining device. In line with existing theories, there exists a curse of the uninterested voter: When voters hav… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1

Citation Types

3
24
0

Year Published

2017
2017
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
6
1

Relationship

2
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 36 publications
(29 citation statements)
references
References 33 publications
3
24
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Our model can easily be extended to the voter observing whether candidates have incurred some (minimum) level of expenditures (the extensive margin) as long as she does not learn the total amount spent (the intensive margin) consistently with reporting requirement in the United States. 10 Finally, Prato and Wolton (2016a) show that the assumption of a representative voter plays no substantive role (despite the possibility of free-riding in a large electorate).…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 3 more Smart Citations
“…Our model can easily be extended to the voter observing whether candidates have incurred some (minimum) level of expenditures (the extensive margin) as long as she does not learn the total amount spent (the intensive margin) consistently with reporting requirement in the United States. 10 Finally, Prato and Wolton (2016a) show that the assumption of a representative voter plays no substantive role (despite the possibility of free-riding in a large electorate).…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Following Dewatripont and Tirole (2005) and Hafer and Landa (2007), in our model, receivers' information is endogenous to their attention and to senders' communication effort. While Prato and Wolton (2016a) are the first to adapt this modeling approach to electoral campaigns, their analysis of the relationship between voter interest in politics and attention to campaigns assumes perfect symmetry between candidates, and is thus completely silent about the role of electoral imbalances, as well as the resulting empirical implications. Other models of electoral campaigns are unidirectional: with either candidates informing voters (e.g., Prat, 2002;Coate, 2004;Ashworth, 2006;Dewan and Hortala-Vallve, 2016;Prato and Wolton, 2016b) or voters learning about candidates (e.g., Martinelli, 2006;Svolik, 2013;Hortala-Vallve and Larcinese, 2016).…”
Section: Formal Literature On Electoral Imbalancesmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…6 In our model, voters cannot commit to ignoring information from the opponent's campaign and this induces a higher-than-optimal level of reform by the incumbent. Over-reform due to competitive interaction in a campaign between politicians is also a feature in Prato and Wolton (2014). Relatedly, Bektimirov and Montagnes (2014) extend the classic model of electoral accountability (Barro (1973) and Ferejohn (1986)) to explore aspects of a specific set of reforms, namely privatisation.…”
Section: Related Literaturementioning
confidence: 99%