1979
DOI: 10.2307/2553187
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The Theory of Market Pre-emption: The Persistence of Excess Capacity and Monopoly in Growing Spatial Markets

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

2
72
0
1

Year Published

1988
1988
2020
2020

Publication Types

Select...
7
1
1

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 188 publications
(75 citation statements)
references
References 7 publications
2
72
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…Speci…cally, the e¤ects are driven by distribution, measured by the number of outlets in a market: of 115:3%, 101:7% comes directly from higher outlet shares ("outlet-share advantage") for …rst entrants, and the remaining 13:6% comes from better sales performance at the store level ("sales-per-outlet advantage") for …rst entrants. The signi…cant outlet-share advantage for …rst entrants is qualitatively consistent with a strand of literature that argues a multistore incumbent may deter late entrants by credibly preempting a product space through product proliferation (e.g., Prescott and Visscher 1977;Schmalensee 1978;Eaton and Lipsey 1979) in geographical space. On the other hand, this paper …nds the observed sales-per-outlet advantage does not exist with a set of controls for the density of own outlets.…”
Section: Introductionsupporting
confidence: 77%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Speci…cally, the e¤ects are driven by distribution, measured by the number of outlets in a market: of 115:3%, 101:7% comes directly from higher outlet shares ("outlet-share advantage") for …rst entrants, and the remaining 13:6% comes from better sales performance at the store level ("sales-per-outlet advantage") for …rst entrants. The signi…cant outlet-share advantage for …rst entrants is qualitatively consistent with a strand of literature that argues a multistore incumbent may deter late entrants by credibly preempting a product space through product proliferation (e.g., Prescott and Visscher 1977;Schmalensee 1978;Eaton and Lipsey 1979) in geographical space. On the other hand, this paper …nds the observed sales-per-outlet advantage does not exist with a set of controls for the density of own outlets.…”
Section: Introductionsupporting
confidence: 77%
“…A model of sequential-move games predicts that in a subgame perfect equilibrium, the "leader," or the …rst entrant, produces a larger quantity and obtains a higher payo¤ than the followers (Stackelberg 1934). In the context of spatial competition, Prescott and Visscher (1977), Schmalensee (1978), Eaton and Lipsey (1979), and Bonanno (1987) By contrast, another strand of literature predicts the sequential move by players may not allow the incumbents to proliferate outlets. For instance, unless the incumbent's exit costs are not too high, entry deterrence against new entrants through product proliferation may not be credible for incumbents (Judd 1985).…”
Section: Theoretical Frameworkmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Consistent with Dixit's arguments, Eaton and Lipsey (1979) showed that capacity expansion, just at the point in time when entry is profitable, deters entry and is profit maximising for an incumbent firm. Ghemawat's (1984) study provided empirical support for Eaton and Lipsey's suggestion that capacity expansion by incumbent firms deters entry.…”
Section: Pre-emption Based On Credible Commitment To React Aggressivelysupporting
confidence: 56%
“…Second, as we show below, which firm excludes in this region can have important welfare implications -unlike the standard contestable markets model, from an efficiency perspective it is not a matter of indifference which firm operates and which firm is excluded. 9 Provided that both consumer participation constraints are slack at prices, { } , S S I E P P . As an inspection of Figure 3 readily shows, the equilibrium cannot lie in the conical region when either consumer participation condition binds.…”
Section: Proposition 3 (Exclusion By the Profitable Seller)mentioning
confidence: 99%